\\server05\productn\N\NYU\82-5\NYU505.txt unknown Seq: 1 16-OCT-07 14:37
IMPOSING LIMITS ON PROSECUTORIAL
DISCRETION IN CORPORATE
PROSECUTION AGREEMENTS
E
RIK
P
AULSEN
*
In late 2006, the Department of Justice (DOJ) overhauled its internal policy
regarding the prosecution of corporate entities. The new policy—expressed in the
“McNulty Memo”—was issued as a direct response to charges that the DOJ had
abused its leverage over the companies it targeted for criminal prosecution, specifi-
cally with regard to compelled cooperation. The McNulty Memo addressed these
charges, in part, by restricting the discretion of individual prosecutors and requiring
approval by the Deputy Attorney General on significant prosecutorial decisions.
While the changes ushered in by the McNulty Memo are a promising first step, they
will not remedy all of the potentially abusive practices that mar the prosecution of
corporate entities—particularly in regard to the use of deferred and non-
prosecution agreements. At first blush, deferred and non-prosecution agreements
appear to present a win-win situation: They offer the benefits of criminal punish-
ment without the negative collateral consequences that flow from criminal charges.
Their increased use, however, has revealed a different picture. By removing the
threat of collateral consequences, deferred and non-prosecution agreements allow
individual prosecutors to take full advantage of the unique weaknesses of corpora-
tions in the criminal justice system. These weaknesses provide prosecutors with a
dangerous amount of leverage over the corporations they target, creating a bar-
gaining imbalance and a new threat of abuse.
The potential for abuse that flows from the use of deferred and non-prosecution
agreements should be addressed by restricting the discretion of individual prosecu-
tors. This Note argues that the DOJ should look to the solution offered in the
McNulty Memo and require that individual prosecutors receive permission from
the Deputy Attorney General before entering into any deferred or non-prosecution
agreement.
I
NTRODUCTION
Early in the morning of December 12, 2006, Paul McNulty, then
Deputy Attorney General of the Department of Justice (DOJ), strode
to the podium at the Lawyers for Civil Justice Conference in New
* Copyright
2007 by Erik Paulsen. J.D., 2007, New York University School of Law;
B.A., 1998, Brown University. I would like to express my gratitude to Emily Bishop, Mitra
Ebadolahi, David Kamen, Mario Mendalaro, Paul Monteleoni, Andrew Purcell, Matt
Reagan, and the staff of the New York University Law Review, for their collective work on
this Note. Special thanks are owed to Mathew Miller for his tireless efforts throughout the
production process. Lastly, I am greatly indebted to Denis McInerney and Professor
Harry First, both of whom graciously offered their time and insight to this project.
1434
\\server05\productn\N\NYU\82-5\NYU505.txt unknown Seq: 2 16-OCT-07 14:37
November 2007] CORPORATE PROSECUTION AGREEMENTS 1435
York City.
1
It was perhaps fitting that Mr. McNulty was surrounded
by an audience attired in dark suits, for he came to give a eulogy. He
told the audience that the “Thompson Memo,” scourge of corporate
America, had been laid to rest.
2
For nearly four years, the Thompson Memo had served as the
touchstone for all DOJ efforts to root out corporate fraud. Written in
the wake of the accounting scandals that engulfed companies like
Enron, Arthur Andersen, and WorldCom, it guided prosecutors in
deciding whether or not to pursue criminal charges against a corpora-
tion.
3
Use of the Thompson Memo guidelines, however, led to allega-
tions of abuse. These allegations focused principally on two kinds of
cooperation requests permitted under the Thompson Memo: requests
for waiver of corporate attorney-client privilege and requests for com-
pany refusal to pay employee legal fees. A diverse range of interests
argued that the DOJ was abusing its power by repeatedly demanding
these kinds of cooperation.
4
Condemnation came from all directions,
and the Thompson Memo could not withstand the collective weight of
the attacks.
5
When McNulty took the podium on December 12, 2006,
he was there to announce a new DOJ policy—expressed in the
1
Paul J. McNulty, U.S. Deputy Att’y Gen., Prepared Remarks of Deputy Attorney
General Paul J. McNulty at the Lawyers for Civil Justice Membership Conference
Regarding the Department’s Charging Guidelines for Corporate Fraud Prosecutions (Dec.
12, 2006), available at http://www.usdoj.gov/dag/speech/2006/dag_speech_061212.htm
[hereinafter McNulty Speech].
2
Id. (“Today I’m announcing revisions to the Thompson Memorandum. The previous
guidance is superseded, and a new memorandum, under my signature, will provide revised
guidance to corporate fraud prosecutors across the country.”).
3
See infra notes 77–85 and accompanying text.
4
See Jason McLure, Coalition Scores Major Victory in Policy Retreat: How Business,
Civil Liberties Groups Pushed DOJ To Alter Fraud Stance, L
EGAL
T
IMES
, Dec. 18, 2006, at
1.
5
A wide variety of organizations and individuals criticized the cooperation provisions
in the Thompson Memo. The American Civil Liberties Union and American Bar
Association (ABA) combined lobbying efforts with strange bedfellows like the National
Association of Manufacturers and the U.S. Chamber of Commerce. McLure, supra note 4.
Ex-attorneys general and solicitors general from previous administrations, both
Republican and Democrat, co-signed a letter asking for a repeal of the practice. Jason
McLure, Ex-DOJ Officials Blast Current Policy: Letter Signed by Bell, Thornburgh, and
Others Criticizes Approach Outlined in Thompson Memo, L
EGAL
T
IMES
, Sept. 11, 2006, at
18. Senator Arlen Specter introduced legislation to change DOJ policy. Lynnley
Browning, Senator Calls for an Easing of Corporate-Wrongdoing Rules, N.Y. T
IMES
, Dec.
8, 2006, at C3. A federal judge in New York declared the Memo, in part, unconstitutional.
United States v. Stein, 435 F. Supp. 2d 330, 365 (S.D.N.Y. 2006). Even Thompson himself,
the eponymous author of the memorandum, expressed reservations. See Lynnley
Browning, Former Deputy at Justice Dept. Would Limit Legal Disclosure, N.Y. T
IMES
, Dec.
1, 2006, at C6 (quoting Thompson as saying that use of waiver should be “extremely
limited”).
\\server05\productn\N\NYU\82-5\NYU505.txt unknown Seq: 3 16-OCT-07 14:37
1436 NEW YORK UNIVERSITY LAW REVIEW [Vol. 82:1434
“McNulty Memo”
6
—that addressed the issues that had provoked such
vigorous opposition.
While the modifications in the McNulty Memo may indeed prove
significant, it would be foolish to think that they will completely solve
the problem of abuse in the prosecution of corporate entities. The
world of corporate prosecution has undergone a revolution during the
past decade, ushering in changes that will survive the replacement of
the Thompson Memo. Foremost among these changes is the wide-
spread use by federal prosecutors of deferred and non-prosecution
agreements. The use of these agreements has created the potential for
a different kind of abuse, which the McNulty Memo does not address.
Deferred and non-prosecution agreements are essentially proba-
tionary agreements between a prosecutor and a corporation suspected
of criminal conduct.
7
Prosecutors agree to waive or defer criminal
prosecution of the corporate entity in exchange for a variety of corpo-
rate promises. These concessions often include massive fines, internal
reforms, and assistance in prosecuting corporate employees.
8
The use
of these agreements exploded after the demise of the corporate
accounting giant Arthur Andersen. When Andersen collapsed after
its indictment, federal prosecutors realized that prosecution alone
could destroy even the most established of companies.
It is in this context that corporate prosecutors turned to deferred
and non-prosecution agreements, which serve as a middle ground
between full prosecution and declination.
9
These agreements allow
prosecutors to punish corporations without risking total corporate col-
lapse—an arrangement that appears to benefit both parties. This
seemingly beneficial dynamic, however, hides a new potential for
abuse. It has become increasingly clear that the government holds all
the cards in negotiations over these agreements. As long as the threat
of prosecution lingers over a company, the corporation is compelled
to agree to the prosecutor’s terms, vesting nearly absolute power in
the government’s hands. Unable to risk a potential indictment, the
corporation is thus left at the mercy of the prosecutor.
This bargaining imbalance is not easily rectified—in fact, there
may not be any true solution short of changing the law of corporate
6
Memorandum from Paul J. McNulty, U.S. Deputy Att’y Gen., to Heads of Dep’t
Components and U.S. Att’ys (Dec. 12, 2006), available at http://www.usdoj.gov/dag/speech/
2006/mcnulty_memo.pdf [hereinafter McNulty Memo].
7
See infra Part I.A.
8
See infra Part I.B.
9
Declination means to decline to prosecute criminally. Benjamin M. Greenblum,
What Happens to a Prosecution Deferred? Judicial Oversight of Corporate Deferred Prose-
cution Agreements, 105 C
OLUM
. L. R
EV
. 1863, 1868 (2005).
\\server05\productn\N\NYU\82-5\NYU505.txt unknown Seq: 4 16-OCT-07 14:37
November 2007] CORPORATE PROSECUTION AGREEMENTS 1437
criminal liability. The abusive tendencies of this bargaining imbalance
can, however, be limited by constraining prosecutorial discretion.
This Note argues that decisions related to deferred and non-
prosecution agreements—both the offer of an agreement as well as its
terms—should be channeled through a formal approval process at the
DOJ in Washington, D.C. rather than decided by individual federal
prosecutors.
10
This process would mirror the procedures already
adopted in the McNulty Memo to handle requests for waiver of
attorney-client privilege. Although this approach would not alter the
bargaining disparity between corporations and prosecutors, it would
curb the potential for abuse by subjecting the decisionmaking of indi-
vidual prosecutors to centralized review. Procedures of this sort
would impose some consistency and uniformity on what has hitherto
been a decentralized and haphazard process.
Part I of this Note details the modern use of corporate prosecu-
tion agreements. Part II reviews the expansive nature of the black
letter law of corporate liability and outlines the procedures developed
by the DOJ to guide prosecutorial discretion. Part III highlights the
steadily growing power of individual prosecutors in the negotiation of
corporate prosecution agreements and points out some early signs of
abuse. Part IV criticizes various remedies that have been proposed to
rein in potential abuse and proposes an expansion of the remedy pro-
vided in the McNulty Memo.
I
P
ROSECUTION
A
GREEMENTS
This Part provides a detailed look at the use of deferred and non-
prosecution agreements. Part I.A lays out the basics of prosecution
agreements: what they are and how they work. Part I.B reviews some
of the common terms of prosecution agreements. Part I.C makes two
significant observations about these agreements: First, prosecutors
retain almost complete discretion in crafting the terms; and second,
these agreements are becoming ever more common.
A. What Are Prosecution Agreements?
A federal prosecutor seeking a middle ground between a prose-
cution and declination has two principal options: a deferred prosecu-
tion agreement or a non-prosecution agreement.
11
A deferred
10
See infra Part IV.B.
11
This is, of course, a bit simplistic. A prosecutor can arrange for civil penalties with
the Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC), for example, instead of pursuing any kind
of criminal discipline. Such options, however, essentially amount to declinations.
\\server05\productn\N\NYU\82-5\NYU505.txt unknown Seq: 5 16-OCT-07 14:37
1438 NEW YORK UNIVERSITY LAW REVIEW [Vol. 82:1434
prosecution agreement is essentially a probationary agreement
arranged between a corporation and the government.
12
In lieu of
criminally prosecuting the entity, the government files some kind of
criminal charge—normally a complaint, information, or indictment
but then agrees to hold the charge open as long as the corporation
successfully fulfills the terms of the agreement.
13
If the prosecutor
deems the agreement’s terms satisfied, the charges are dismissed.
While non-prosecution agreements are identical to deferred pros-
ecution agreements in most respects, there are two key differences.
First, in a non-prosecution agreement the prosecutor does not file a
charging instrument. In some circumstances, this can be a significant
difference: Mere indictment can trigger penalties for certain corpora-
tions.
14
Second, non-prosecution agreements normally send a less stri-
dent message to the market—the absence of the charging instrument
often indicates a lower level of culpability.
15
As a result, potential
defendants prefer non-prosecution agreements.
16
In most other respects, however, the two types of agreements—
especially those signed since the introduction of the Thompson
Memo—tend to have identical terms and qualities.
17
In fact, some
non-prosecution agreements can be as harsh as their deferred counter-
parts.
18
For the purposes of this Note, I will treat them as one and the
12
Despite their frequent use today, prosecution agreements were not engineered in the
context of corporate liability. Rather, they began as a means to rehabilitate juvenile
offenders. Greenblum, supra note 9, at 1864. It was not until the early 1990s that agree-
ments of this type were used to settle criminal charges against entities. Id.
13
Eugene Illovsky, Corporate Deferred Prosecution Agreements: The Brewing Debate,
C
RIM
. J
UST
., Summer 2006, at 36, 36, available at http://www.abanet.org/crimjust/cjmag/21-
2/corporatedeferred.pdf.
14
Interview with David Pitofsky, C
ORP
. C
RIME
R
EP
., Nov. 28, 2005, at 8, 13.
15
See id. (noting that a non-prosecution agreement “communicates something that is
substantially less harsh than a deferred prosecution agreement . . . [and] provides the pros-
ecutor with the ability to send a graded message about the seriousness of the misconduct”).
16
Id.
17
Id.
18
The HealthSouth Non-Prosecution Agreement, for example, features a three-year,
six-month duration; over $500 million in penalties and restitution; substantial internal gov-
ernance reforms; and a compliance monitor. Non-Prosecution Agreement Between U.S.
Dep’t of Justice and HealthSouth Corp., paras. 3, 8–9 (May 18, 2006) (on file with the
New York University Law Review) [hereinafter HealthSouth NPA]. The Boeing Non-
Prosecution Agreement features a two-year duration; over $600 million in penalties; sub-
stantial internal governance reforms; and an agreement to provide a limited privilege
waiver. Non-Prosecution Agreement Between U.S. Att’y’s Office for E. Dist. Va. and
Boeing Co., paras. 3–4, 6–7 (June 30, 2006) (on file with the New York University Law
Review) [hereinafter Boeing NPA]. These conditions are comparable to modern deferred
prosecution agreements. E.g., Deferred Prosecution Agreement Between U.S. Att’y’s
Office for S. Dist. of N.Y. and KPMG, para. 3 (Aug. 26, 2005) (on file with the New York
University Law Review) [hereinafter KPMG DPA] (noting substantial penalties, internal
business reforms, and privilege waiver).
\\server05\productn\N\NYU\82-5\NYU505.txt unknown Seq: 6 16-OCT-07 14:37
November 2007] CORPORATE PROSECUTION AGREEMENTS 1439
same—when I use the term “prosecution agreements,” I am generally
referring to both deferred and non-prosecution agreements, noting
differences only where relevant.
19
B. Elements of Prosecution Agreements
Prosecution agreements feature a wide variety of terms. These
include, inter alia, provisions about cooperation, acknowledgment of
criminal conduct, business reforms, penalties, and independent
monitors.
Cooperation: Corporate cooperation has been the most contro-
versial element of prosecution agreements. In particular, negative
attention has focused on two common prosecutorial practices:
requests that the company refuse to pay attorneys’ fees for employees
suspected of criminal conduct,
20
and requests that the company waive
19
The overwhelming majority of these agreements share the same features despite
their different titles. If a distinction is to be drawn regarding the agreements’ terms, one
might separate out the early non-prosecution agreements from the rest. For example,
many of the early non-prosecution agreements did not feature any set duration—that is,
once the agreement was signed, the company’s relationship with the prosecutor’s office
was essentially over. Of the fifty-nine agreements signed between 1992 and 2006, seven fit
this mold: the Aurora Agreement, the Lazard Agreement, the Merrill Lynch First Agree-
ment, the John Hancock Agreement, the AETNA Agreement, the Sequa Agreement, and
the Salomon Brothers Agreement. See Lawrence D. Finder & Ryan D. McConnell, Devo-
lution of Authority: The Department of Justice’s Corporate Charging Policies, 51 S
T
. L
OUIS
U. L.J. 1, 6–7, app. (2006) (indicating that six of seven agreements signed before 1999 did
not contain explicit expiration dates); infra notes 46–47 (noting fifty-nine total agreements
from 1992 to 2006). These seven agreements are probably best described as official state-
ments detailing the reasons why the government declined to prosecute the organization in
question.
Once the Holder Memo was released, nearly all deferred and non-prosecution agree-
ments took on the same form. Memorandum from Eric H. Holder Jr., U.S. Deputy Att’y
Gen., to All Component Heads and U.S. Att’ys (June 16, 1999) (on file with the New York
University Law Review) [hereinafter Holder Memo]. Of the seven agreements noted
above which differ from the modern form, six were signed before 1999, the date that the
Holder Memo was issued. The one exception to this generalization is the Aurora
Agreement, which was signed in 2001 and is perhaps best treated as an anomaly. See Non-
Prosecution Agreement Between U.S. Att’y’s Office for S. Dist. of N.Y. and Aurora Food
(Jan. 22, 2001) (on file with the New York University Law Review). Other than the Aurora
Agreement, all the deferred and non-prosecution agreements issued since 1999 are suffi-
ciently similar that they can be spoken of as a group.
20
Many corporations, either by explicit employment contract or by historical practice,
provide their employees with attorneys’ fees to cover criminal allegations involving actions
committed in the course of employment. United States v. Stein, 435 F. Supp. 2d 330,
353–55 (S.D.N.Y. 2006) (summarizing historical practice of employers indemnifying
employees for legal expenses). In certain circumstances, prosecutors have frowned on
these agreements, and have pressured companies to waive or limit these arrangements to
demonstrate cooperation. The Thompson Memo explicitly stated that the advancement of
attorneys’ fees might be evidence of non-cooperation as the company is “protecting . . .
culpable employees and agents.” Memorandum from Larry D. Thompson, U.S. Deputy
Att’y Gen., to Heads of Dep’t Components and U.S. Att’ys § VI(B), at 7–8 (Jan. 20, 2003),
\\server05\productn\N\NYU\82-5\NYU505.txt unknown Seq: 7 16-OCT-07 14:37
1440 NEW YORK UNIVERSITY LAW REVIEW [Vol. 82:1434
attorney-client privilege.
21
Controversy over these practices eventu-
ally resulted in the replacement of the Thompson Memo with the
McNulty Memo.
22
Although these issues are of tremendous significance, this Note
will not focus on the potential for abuse in the cooperation provisions
of prosecution agreements for two important reasons. First, com-
pelled cooperation has already received considerable attention. To
the extent that commentators have examined the use and abuse of
prosecution agreements, criticism has mainly focused on the issue of
cooperation.
23
Second, and more significantly, the abuses identified in
these practices are moving toward a legal remedy: The McNulty
Memo is a clear indication that the DOJ is expending serious effort to
address potential abuse in prosecutorial practices related to coopera-
tion. The same, however, cannot be said for the other provisions of
prosecution agreements. Accordingly this Note will focus on the
potential for prosecutorial abuse in these other provisions.
Acknowledgement of Conduct: The majority of prosecution
agreements, especially those signed since the introduction of the
Thompson Memo, require the company to acknowledge responsibility
available at http://www.usdoj.gov/dag/cftf/business_organizations.pdf [hereinafter
Thompson Memo].
21
The Thompson Memo stated that a corporation’s willingness to waive attorney-client
privilege was highly relevant evidence of a corporation’s cooperation. Thompson Memo,
supra note 20, § VI(B), at 6–7. While the Thompson Memo stated that such waiver was
not an “absolute requirement,” id., many practitioners found that prosecutors demanded
disclosure of privileged documents in nearly all circumstances. Companies that resisted
risked appearing uncooperative. Stephen W. Grafman & Jeffrey L. Bornstein, New Memo
Won’t Help, N
AT
L
L.J., Nov. 14, 2005, at 31, 31 (“In reality today, a corporation that does
not waive these valuable privilege rights effectively is considered a non-cooperator.”).
22
See supra note 6 and accompanying text.
23
See, e.g., Am. Coll. of Trial Lawyers, The Erosion of the Attorney-Client Privilege and
Work Product Doctrine in Federal Criminal Investigations, 41 D
UQ
. L. R
EV
. 307, 321–22
(2003) (criticizing government for asking for privilege waiver); Mary Beth Buchanan,
Effective Cooperation by Business Organizations and the Impact of Privilege Waivers, 39
W
AKE
F
OREST
L. R
EV
. 587, 595–607 (2004) (summarizing and responding to criticisms of
privilege waiver); George Ellard, Making the Silent Speak and the Informed Wary, 42 A
M
.
C
RIM
. L. R
EV
. 985, 992–93 (2005) (criticizing pressure exerted on companies to waive
attorney-client privilege); Lisa Kern Griffin, Compelled Cooperation and the New Corpo-
rate Criminal Procedure, 82 N.Y.U. L. R
EV
. 311, 319–21 (2007) (discussing Thompson
Memo factors for assessing corporate cooperation, which include corporation’s identifica-
tion and sanctioning of employees); Joseph F. Savage, Jr. & Melissa M. Longo, ‘Waive’
Goodbye to Attorney-Client Privilege, B
US
. C
RIMES
B
ULL
., Oct. 2000, at 1, 8 (discussing
waiver in context of inadvertant disclosure); Mary Jo White, Corporate Criminal Liability:
What Has Gone Wrong?, in 2 37
TH
A
NNUAL
I
NSTITUTE ON
S
ECURITIES
R
EGULATION
815,
821 (PLI Corporate Law & Practice, Course Handbook Series No. B-1517, 2005) (arguing
that waiver has “become a heavy stick and a company, only at its extreme peril, declines a
prosecutor’s request for waiver”); Christopher A. Wray & Robert K. Hur, Corporate Crim-
inal Prosecution in a Post-Enron World: The Thompson Memo in Theory and Practice, 43
A
M
. C
RIM
. L. R
EV
. 1095, 1170–74 (2006) (summarizing criticisms of cooperation policy).
\\server05\productn\N\NYU\82-5\NYU505.txt unknown Seq: 8 16-OCT-07 14:37
November 2007] CORPORATE PROSECUTION AGREEMENTS 1441
for the conduct in question. The company and the government agree
to a “statement of facts” that details the government’s allegations.
24
The company stipulates to the conduct alleged in the statement of
facts and consents to admission of the statement as evidence if the
prosecution agreement is breached. If this occurs, there is essentially
a corporate confession to the charge.
25
The power of these provisions
is worth noting: Detailed admissions to criminal charges typically
result in lucrative civil suits that piggyback on the signing of these
agreements.
26
For many corporations, “the ripple effect” of these
admissions is catastrophic.
27
The fact that corporations typically agree
to these admissions—despite the consequences in civil suits—under-
scores the degree to which corporations desire to avoid criminal
indictment and/or conviction.
Monetary Penalties: Modern prosecution agreements generally
feature significant monetary penalties, which can involve a combina-
tion of criminal penalties, civil penalties, and civil settlements to non-
governmental plaintiffs—often in staggering amounts. For example,
Boeing’s non-prosecution agreement called for a $565 million civil set-
tlement and a $50 million criminal penalty.
28
KPMG was ordered to
pay $456 million—$128 million in disgorged fees, $288 million in resti-
tution to the Internal Revenue Service (IRS), and a $100 million pen-
alty to the IRS.
29
These numbers are not unusual—numerous
agreements feature settlements worth hundreds of millions of dol-
lars.
30
Other agreements call for more unorthodox penalties, such as
the provision requiring $4 million worth of free medical services in the
24
E.g., Deferred Prosecution Agreement Between U.S. Dep’t of Justice and
BankAtlantic, para. 2 (Apr. 26, 2006) (on file with the New York University Law Review);
Deferred Prosecution Agreement Between U.S. Dep’t of Justice and Monsanto Co., para.
4 (Jan. 6, 2005) (on file with the New York University Law Review).
25
E.g., Boeing NPA, supra note 18, para. 12(a)(4); Deferred Prosecution Agreement
Between U.S. Att’y’s Office for D. of Conn. and Operations Mgmt. Int’l, para. 9 (Feb. 8,
2006) (on file with the New York University Law Review) [hereinafter OMI DPA].
26
Admissions within a prosecution agreement can have significant consequences on
subsequent or pending litigation, as “a plaintiff will seek to use [them] against the corpora-
tion in later civil proceedings.” Michael R. Sklaire & Joshua G. Berman, Deferred Prose-
cution Agreements: What Is the Cost of Staying in Business?, L
EGAL
O
PINION
L
ETTER
,
June 3, 2005, at 2, available at http://www.sonnenschein.com/docs/Cost_of_Staying_in_B.
pdf.
27
See Stephanie Martz, Trends in Deferred Prosecution Agreements, C
HAMPION
, Nov.
2005, at 45, 45 (“[F]or corporations, the ripple effect of these admissions could be
devastating.”).
28
Boeing NPA, supra note 18, para. 4(b)–(c).
29
KPMG DPA, supra note 18, para. 3.
30
See Finder & McConnell, supra note 19, app. (noting various prosecution agree-
ments with nine-figure fines).
\\server05\productn\N\NYU\82-5\NYU505.txt unknown Seq: 9 16-OCT-07 14:37
1442 NEW YORK UNIVERSITY LAW REVIEW [Vol. 82:1434
prosecution agreement with Roger Williams Hospital.
31
While such
settlements are not the norm, they evince a potential for abuse: Pros-
ecutors have wide flexibility and few barriers in crafting penalties.
Business Reforms: Prosecution agreements often require the
target company to make significant changes to the way it conducts
business. Some of the more common undertakings involve personnel.
The agreement might call for the termination or disciplining of
employees for either contributing to the underlying criminal conduct
32
or for failure to cooperate with the investigation.
33
Required changes
might also include the hiring of new senior management,
34
new board
members,
35
or new auditors.
36
The other common type of business reform involves operational
changes. Perhaps the most common are enhancements to compliance
programs, which can include, among other measures, amended finan-
cial controls, hotlines for whistleblowers, training programs to under-
score legal behavior, new personnel hiring policies, and ethics
officers.
37
These business reforms have also raised concern. Shareholders
traditionally control decisions regarding the staffing of boards of
directors, which in turn control the staffing of management. Prosecu-
tors are not businessmen, and some commentators have questioned
the wisdom of permitting prosecutorial intrusion into the internal
workings of large corporations.
38
31
Deferred Prosecution Agreement Between U.S. Att’y’s Office for Dist. of R.I. and
Roger Williams Med. Ctr., para. 12 (Jan. 27, 2006) (on file with the New York University
Law Review) [hereinafter Roger Williams DPA].
32
E.g., Non-Prosecution Agreement Among U.S. Att’y’s Office for E. Dist. of N.Y.,
U.S. Att’y’s Office for S. Dist. of N.Y. and Bank of New York, para. 10(a) (Nov. 8, 2005)
(on file with the New York University Law Review); HealthSouth NPA, supra note 18,
para. 8(a).
33
Non-Prosecution Agreement Between U.S. Att’y’s Office for E. Dist. of N.Y. and
Symbol Techs., para. 9(b) (June 3, 2004) (on file with the New York University Law
Review) [hereinafter Symbol NPA].
34
E.g., HealthSouth NPA, supra note 18, para. 8(b); Symbol NPA, supra note 33, para.
9(c).
35
E.g., HealthSouth NPA, supra note 18, para. 8(d); Deferred Prosecution Agreement
Between U.S. Att’y’s Office for S. Dist. of N.Y. and Prudential Secs., Inc. 3 (Oct. 27, 1994)
(on file with the New York University Law Review).
36
E.g., HealthSouth NPA, supra note 18, para. 8(c); Symbol NPA, supra note 33, para.
9(d).
37
E.g., OMI DPA, supra note 25, paras. 5–6.
38
Professor John C. Coffee argues, for example, that there is little to stop a prosecutor
from demanding as a condition of deferred prosecution that a board without much diver-
sity reconstitute itself as half female and at least one-third minority. John C. Coffee Jr.,
Deferred Prosecution: Has It Gone Too Far? N
AT
L
L.J., July 25, 2005, at 13, 13. Coffee
believes that shareholders should have the right to choose their own directors, and such
interference by prosecutors goes beyond their “competence or entitlement.” Id.
\\server05\productn\N\NYU\82-5\NYU505.txt unknown Seq: 10 16-OCT-07 14:37
November 2007] CORPORATE PROSECUTION AGREEMENTS 1443
Independent Monitors: A large percentage of modern prosecu-
tion agreements require compliance monitors—independent experts
retained to supervise compliance with the agreement who report peri-
odically to the prosecutor.
39
These monitors are normally either com-
pliance specialists or august members of the legal community.
40
The
corporation pays the costs of the monitor and his/her staff and is
expected to give the monitor relatively unfettered access to business
operations.
41
For some, the monitor’s very presence assuages con-
cerns about prosecutorial expertise in business regulation.
42
Others,
however, generally doubt the wisdom of allowing prosecutors to inter-
pose their power into sensitive boardroom decisions, arguing that such
business decisions are beyond prosecutors’ expertise.
43
Miscellaneous Penalties: Some of these agreements contain unu-
sual provisions which defy categorization. Prosecutors have signifi-
cant leeway as to what conditions they demand of the target
corporations, and there is little to stop a prosecutor from crafting
unique penalties. For example, the agreement between WorldCom
and the Attorney General of Oklahoma required the company to
create sixteen hundred new jobs over a ten-year period.
44
Similarly,
the Bristol-Meyers Squibb Agreement mandated the creation of an
endowed chair in business ethics at Seton Hall Law School, the local
U.S. Attorney’s alma mater.
45
39
See Finder & McConnell, supra note 19, app. (tabulating terms of deferred and non-
prosecution agreements, including monitors).
40
In the Bristol-Meyers Squibb Agreement, for example, the prosecutor and company
agreed to use Frederick B. Lacey, a former U.S. Attorney and federal judge. Deferred
Prosecution Agreement Between U.S. Att’y’s Office for D.N.J. and Bristol-Meyers Squibb
Co., para. 5 (June 15, 2005) (on file with the New York University Law Review) [herein-
after Bristol-Meyers DPA].
41
E.g., Roger Williams DPA, supra note 31, paras. 21–31; HealthSouth NPA, supra
note 18, para. 11.
42
See Christopher J. Christie & Robert M. Hanna, A Push Down the Road of Good
Corporate Citizenship: The Deferred Prosecution Agreement Between the U.S. Attorney for
the District of New Jersey and Bristol-Meyers Squibb Co., 43 A
M
. C
RIM
. L. R
EV
. 1043, 1055
(2006) (“A strong, independent monitor is in a far better position to ride herd over a
mammoth corporation than any U.S. Attorney’s Office or Probation Office. . . . Monitors
are able to observe and understand the business they oversee, . . . in ways that federal
prosecutors never could or should.”); Interview with David Pitofsky, supra note 14, at 9
(“One of the reasons why the deferred prosecution agreements require a monitor to be put
in place is that the prosecutor’s office has no experience or skills to analyze whether a
company is reforming its internal governance practices.”).
43
See supra notes 32–38 and accompanying text.
44
Deferred Prosecution Agreement Between State of Oklahoma and WorldCom, Inc.
2 (Mar. 12, 2004) (on file with the New York University Law Review).
45
Bristol-Meyers DPA, supra note 40, para. 20. The OMI Agreement contains a sim-
ilar provision with the Coast Guard Academy. OMI DPA, supra note 25, app. A.
Christopher Christie, the U.S. Attorney who negotiated the Bristol-Meyers Squibb Agree-
ment, states that the idea of endowing a chair in ethics came from defense counsel. Fur-
\\server05\productn\N\NYU\82-5\NYU505.txt unknown Seq: 11 16-OCT-07 14:37
1444 NEW YORK UNIVERSITY LAW REVIEW [Vol. 82:1434
C. The Use and Frequency of Prosecution Agreements
There are two initial observations that should be made about the
use of prosecution agreements in the corporate criminal context.
First, prosecutors are not significantly limited in what they might
include as conditions in these agreements. As noted above, prosecu-
tion agreements feature a wide variety of terms, often including enor-
mous fines, serious overhauls of business practices, and full admissions
of criminal responsibility. Despite the severity of these conditions,
however, corporations nearly always accept the prosecutor’s terms.
The content of the agreement depends almost entirely on the discre-
tion of the prosecutor; what the prosecutor asks for, the prosecutor
gets.
A second observation relates to the frequency of these agree-
ments. From 1992 to the end of 2002, the ten years following the first
use of prosecution agreements in the corporate criminal context, there
were sixteen deferred and non-prosecution agreements—an average
of fewer than two a year.
46
From the beginning of 2003 to the end of
2006, however, there were a staggering forty-three prosecution agree-
ments—an average of more than ten a year.
47
And during this latter
ther, Seton Hall was chosen because Rutgers University School of Law already had a chair
in business ethics endowed by Prudential. Christie & Hanna, supra note 42, at 1058 n.29.
46
Finder & McConnell, supra note 19, app. Lawrence Finder and Ryan McConnell
have assembled the most comprehensive index of known agreements. In the appendix to
their article they count ten deferred and non-prosecution agreements during the period
from 1992 to 2002. They intentionally excluded the agreements with Coopers & Lybrand,
Salomon Brothers, and Sequa because those agreements were never made public. Id. at 36
n.193. For the purpose of this counting exercise, however, I am including those three
agreements as well as three agreements not considered by Finder and McConnell—the
agreements with JB Oxford & Co., Hilton Hotels, and Doyon Drilling. Deferred Prosecu-
tion Agreement Among U.S. Att’y’s Office for Cent. Dist. of Cal., JB Oxford Holdings,
Inc., and JB Oxford & Co. (Feb. 12, 2000) (on file with the New York University Law
Review); Press Release, Office of U.S. Att’y for W. Dist. of Mo., Hilton Kansas City
Corporation and Hildeon Gaming Enter Pretrial Diversion Agreement Over Investigation
of $1.25 Million Grant (Aug. 12, 1998) (on file with the New York University Law Review);
Deferred Prosecution Agreement Between U.S. Att’y’s Office for Dist. of Ala. and Doyon
Drilling Inc. (Apr. 1998) (on file with the New York University Law Review).
47
Finder & McConnell, supra note 19, app. Finder and McConnell counted thirty-
eight deferred and non-prosecution agreements between 2003 and 2006. They intention-
ally excluded two agreements from their list: the Hilfiger Agreement, because the agree-
ment was never released to the public, and the WorldCom Agreement, because it was
negotiated with the Attorney General of Oklahoma. For the purposes of this counting
exercise, I have included both agreements. Further, three agreements were signed in the
final months of 2006, too late to be included in Finder and McConnell’s article. These
three agreements—the Statoil Agreement, the SSI Korea Agreement, and the Intermune
Agreement—are also included in my final count of forty-three agreements. Press Release,
U.S. Dep’t of Justice, U.S. Resolves Probe Against Oil Company that Bribed Iranian Offi-
cial (Oct. 13, 2006) (on file with the New York University Law Review); Press Release,
U.S. Dep’t of Justice, Schnitzer Steel Industries Inc.’s Subsidiary Pleads Guilty to Foreign
\\server05\productn\N\NYU\82-5\NYU505.txt unknown Seq: 12 16-OCT-07 14:37
November 2007] CORPORATE PROSECUTION AGREEMENTS 1445
period, the rate of use was still increasing—2006 alone saw eighteen
such agreements.
48
The first of these two observations—that prosecutors possess
wide discretion in crafting agreements—points to a developing
problem of abuse, a concern that will be addressed in Parts III and IV
of this Note. Before addressing the issue of abuse, however, we need
to understand why prosecution agreements have become so common
in the area of corporate criminal liability. The peculiar nature of cor-
porate prosecution—in particular the broad scope of entity liability
and the concern for “collateral consequences”—has provided prose-
cutors with clear incentives to use these agreements with increasing
frequency.
II
P
ROSECUTION
A
GREEMENTS AND
C
ORPORATE
C
RIMINAL
C
ONDUCT
This Part explores reasons why prosecutorial agreements have
become so common in the area of corporate criminal liability. Part
II.A lays out the basic law of corporate criminal liability, which is
astonishingly broad: Any criminal act committed by an employee of a
corporation, if committed within the scope of employment and in part
to benefit the corporation, can be imputed to the corporation itself.
49
Part II.B details some common concerns with entity prosecution, and
goes on to discuss federal prosecutors’ responses. Part I.C focuses on
the most significant of these concerns: the fear of collateral conse-
quences. Typified by the Arthur Andersen collapse, corporate prose-
cution can visit massive harms upon innocent parties who depend
upon the corporation. In part to avoid these effects, prosecutors have
turned to prosecution agreements as a means to punish companies
while sidestepping collateral consequences.
A. The Remarkably Broad Scope of Corporate Criminal Liability
Modern corporate criminal liability was born in 1909 in New York
Central & Hudson River Railroad Co. v. United States.
50
New York
Bribes and Agrees to Pay a $7.5 Million Criminal Fine (Oct. 16, 2006) (on file with the New
York University Law Review); Deferred Prosecution Agreement Between U.S. Att’y’s
Office for N. Dist. of Cal. and Intermune, Inc. (Oct. 28, 2006) (on file with the New York
University Law Review).
48
This count includes the fifteen 2006 agreements listed in Finder and McConnell’s
matrix, as well as the Statoil Agreement, the SSI Korea Agreement, and the Intermune
Agreement. See supra note 47 and accompanying text.
49
See infra notes 54–66 and accompanying text.
50
212 U.S. 481 (1909); Developments in the Law—Corporate Crime: Regulating Corpo-
rate Behavior Through Criminal Sanctions, 92 H
ARV
. L. R
EV
. 1226, 1246 & n.12 (1979).
\\server05\productn\N\NYU\82-5\NYU505.txt unknown Seq: 13 16-OCT-07 14:37
1446 NEW YORK UNIVERSITY LAW REVIEW [Vol. 82:1434
Central was a rate-fixing case: An employee of the defendant railroad
violated federal tariff laws on sugar shipments.
51
Instead of filing
criminal charges solely against the employee, however, the govern-
ment took the radical step of charging both the employee and the cor-
porate employer. Prior to New York Central, no federal standard
existed for charging a corporation with a crime that required intent.
52
Rather, the legal community generally accepted that corporations
could not be charged with criminal behavior because corporations are
fictional persons.
53
New York Central drastically altered the legal landscape. Bor-
rowing the tort law principle of respondeat superior,
54
the Supreme
Court held that a corporate entity could be criminally liable for its
employees’ actions.
55
The imposition of entity liability through the
respondeat superior model addressed two fundamental concerns asso-
ciated with corporate crime. First, entity liability augmented the
deterrent effect of the law: Because corporations often derived bene-
fits from the unlawful practices of their employees, criminal conduct
could only be deterred effectively if the corporation, in addition to its
employees, was subject to prosecution.
56
Second, vicarious corporate
51
N.Y. Cent., 212 U.S. at 489–91.
52
The decision in New York Central was not completely without precedent; there had
been some development of corporate liability for public nuisances and strict liability crimes
before 1909 in non-federal forums. See V. S. Khanna, Corporate Criminal Liability: What
Purpose Does It Serve?, 109 H
ARV
. L. R
EV
. 1477, 1479–82 (1996) (describing evolution of
corporate criminal liability). In addition, Justice Day, the author of the New York Central
opinion, cited a variety of non-federal sources for the proposition that corporations could
be held liable for crimes of intent, including a contemporaneous criminal treatise and court
decisions from Massachusetts and England. N.Y. Cent., 212 U.S. at 492–93. However, as
New York Central was the first case where the Supreme Court explicitly used these prece-
dents in formulating federal law, commentators generally consider this case to be the pro-
genitor of entity liability in the United States. See, e.g., Shaun P. Martin, Intracorporate
Conspiracies, 50 S
TAN
. L. R
EV
. 399, 406–07 (1998) (noting that Supreme Court ratified
previous developments in corporate liability in New York Central, signaling “beginning of
the end of corporate immunity from criminal liability”).
53
See N.Y. Cent., 212 U.S. at 492 (“Some of the earlier writers on common law held the
law to be that a corporation could not commit a crime.”). Specifically, Justice Day noted
that Blackstone’s Commentaries stated, “‘A corporation cannot commit treason, or felony,
or other crime in its corporate capacity, though its members may, in their distinct indi-
vidual capacities.’ Id. (quoting W
ILLIAM
B
LACKSTONE
, 1 C
OMMENTARIES
*476).
54
See id. at 493–94 (describing liability of corporation for acts of employee). Respon-
deat superior is defined as “[t]he doctrine holding an employer or principal liable for the
employee’s or agent’s wrongful acts committed within the scope of employment or
agency.” B
LACK
S
L
AW
D
ICTIONARY
1338 (8th ed. 2004).
55
N.Y. Cent., 212 U.S. at 495–96.
56
See id. (“[T]o give [corporations] immunity from all punishment because of the old
and exploded doctrine that a corporation cannot commit a crime would virtually take away
the only means of effectually controlling the subject-matter and correcting the abuses
aimed at.”); Khanna, supra note 52, at 1483 (describing deterrence as motive for change in
jurisprudence).
\\server05\productn\N\NYU\82-5\NYU505.txt unknown Seq: 14 16-OCT-07 14:37
November 2007] CORPORATE PROSECUTION AGREEMENTS 1447
liability sidestepped the thorny issue of intent: By using the indi-
vidual’s criminal conduct as the basis for the criminal charge against
the corporation, the law could satisfactorily address the issue of how
to establish the mens rea of an inanimate entity.
57
The New York Central Court suggested a two-part test to effec-
tuate this criminal version of respondeat superior: If an employee
committed a crime (1) within the scope of his or her employment and
(2) for the benefit of the corporation, the corporation could be liable
for the employee’s criminal act.
58
This standard remains the law to
this day.
59
The two elements of the New York Central test—“scope of
employment” and “for the benefit”—are not difficult to satisfy. Con-
sequently, virtually every case of employee misconduct could result in
corporate criminal liability. Courts have construed the “scope of
employment” very broadly, covering actions authorized by both
actual
60
and apparent
61
authority. Federal courts have considered
employee actions to be within the scope of employment even where
the corporation expressly forbade the behavior in question, either
with a general policy or with individual admonitions to the culpable
employees.
62
“For the benefit” has also been construed broadly.
Courts do not require that the corporation actually receive a benefit;
it is sufficient that the employee merely intends to benefit the corpo-
57
Cf. Developments in the Law—Corporate Crime: Regulating Corporate Behavior
Through Criminal Sanctions, supra note 50, at 1241 (noting that “mental state has no
meaning when applied to a corporate defendant”).
58
See N.Y. Cent., 212 U.S. at 493–95 (allowing criminal prosecution of corporation
where agents act “within the authority conferred upon them” and where “the corporation
. . . profits by the transaction”).
59
See, e.g., United States v. Philip Morris USA, Inc., 449 F. Supp. 2d 1, 892–93 (D.D.C.
2006) (applying New York Central test of corporate criminal liability).
60
An employee acts with actual authority if “a corporation knowingly and intentionally
authorizes [the] employee to act on its behalf.” Michael Viano & Jenny R. Arnold, Corpo-
rate Criminal Liability, 43 A
M
. C
RIM
. L. R
EV
. 311, 314 (2006); see also Joel M. Androphy
et al., General Corporate Criminal Liability, 60 T
EX
. B. J. 121, 122 (1997) (discussing actual
authority).
61
An employee acts with apparent authority “if a third party reasonably believes that
the [employee] has the authority to perform the act in question.” Viano & Arnold, supra
note 60, at 314; see also Androphy, supra note 60, at 121–22 (discussing apparent
authority).
62
See United States v. Automated Med. Labs., Inc., 770 F.2d 399, 407 (4th Cir. 1985)
(“The fact that many of [the employees’] actions were unlawful and contrary to corporate
policy does not absolve [the defendant-corporation] of legal responsibility for their acts.”);
United States v. Hilton Hotels Corp., 467 F.2d 1000, 1007 (9th Cir. 1972) (holding that
company can be found liable “for the acts of its agents in the scope of their employment,
even though contrary to general corporate policy and express instructions to the agent”).
\\server05\productn\N\NYU\82-5\NYU505.txt unknown Seq: 15 16-OCT-07 14:37
1448 NEW YORK UNIVERSITY LAW REVIEW [Vol. 82:1434
ration.
63
Nor do courts require “that the employee be primarily con-
cerned with benefiting the corporation;”
64
employees may act
principally for their own gain and intend to benefit the corporation
only in a secondary manner.
65
Generally speaking, an employee’s
behavior must be completely inimical to the corporation’s interests—
for example, violating a fiduciary duty owed to the company itself—
for courts to determine that the corporation received no benefit.
66
The New York Central standard thus offers a simple method for
finding a corporation criminally liable. It is a powerful weapon in the
hands of prosecutors since nearly any predicate criminal act by an
employee can lead to a corporate criminal charge. Given the low
threshold of liability established by New York Central, it is natural to
ask why so few corporations are convicted of federal crimes. The
answer is prosecutorial discretion.
B. DOJ Efforts To Guide Prosecutorial Discretion in Corporate
Prosecution: The Holder, Thompson, and McNulty Memos
There are a variety of reasons why a prosecutor might be disin-
clined toward using New York Central’s vicarious criminal liability
standard. Some concerns with vicarious criminal liability border on
the philosophical: The prosecutor may struggle with conceptualizing
corporations as entities capable of intent.
67
For most, however, con-
cerns with vicarious criminal liability are moral or instrumental.
63
See Automated Med. Labs., 770 F.2d at 407 (“[W]hether the agent’s actions ulti-
mately redounded to the benefit of the corporation is less significant than whether the
agent acted with the intent to benefit the corporation.”); Viano & Arnold, supra note 60, at
316 (“The corporation [to be held liable] need not have actually received a benefit; the
employee’s mere intention to bestow such benefit suffices.”).
64
Viano & Arnold, supra note 60, at 316.
65
See Automated Med. Labs., 770 F.2d at 407 (upholding conviction of corporation
based on employee’s acting “at least in part” to benefit corporation); Viano & Arnold,
supra note 60, at 316 (noting that “courts recognize that many employees act primarily for
their own personal gain”).
66
See Standard Oil Co. of Tex. v. United States, 307 F.2d 120, 129 (5th Cir. 1962)
(reversing conviction of corporate defendants because criminal acts of corporate
employees were intended to defraud company itself); Viano & Arnold, supra note 60, at
317 & n.41 (noting that corporation cannot be subject to criminal liability on basis of
employee behavior that is “expressly contrary to the interests of the corporation and for
which the corporation derives no benefit”).
67
Edward, First Baron Thurlow, is famously said to have quipped that a corporation
has “no soul to be damned, and no body to be kicked.” M
ERVYN
K
ING
, P
UBLIC
P
OLICY
AND THE
C
ORPORATION
1 (1977) (attributing quote to Thurlow); John C. Coffee, Jr., “No
Soul to Damn: No Body to Kick”: An Unscandalized Inquiry into the Problem of Corpo-
rate Punishment, 79 M
ICH
. L. R
EV
. 386, 386 & n.1 (1981) (same). On this subject, see
Samuel W. Buell, The Blaming Function of Entity Criminal Liability, 81 I
ND
. L.J. 473, 475
& n.8, 517 & n.191 (2006). Buell observes that scholars have long doubted the logic of
respondeat superior criminal liability, “pointing to illogic in retribution toward objects and
\\server05\productn\N\NYU\82-5\NYU505.txt unknown Seq: 16 16-OCT-07 14:37
November 2007] CORPORATE PROSECUTION AGREEMENTS 1449
Overuse of the vicarious liability standard runs the risk of criminally
condemning an entity that may have had little to do with the criminal
behavior in question.
68
Vicarious criminal liability may overdeter,
compelling risk-averse corporations to steer employees away from
borderline but permissible conduct out of uncertainty over punish-
ment.
69
Efficiency may be best served by reserving criminal liability
for individuals and subjecting corporations to civil penalties.
70
Finally,
and perhaps most significantly, criminal charges against a corporation
can negatively affect shareholders, employees, and communities
dependent on the corporation—parties which may have had no
involvement in the alleged misconduct.
71
These negative effects are
typically described as “collateral consequences”—damages to those
innocent of the wrongdoing in question.
72
In response to these various concerns surrounding the use of cor-
porate liability, the DOJ issued a series of memoranda outlining fac-
tors that federal prosecutors should consider in determining whether
to indict a corporation. These memos, named after their Deputy
Attorney General authors, have served as touchstones for discre-
tionary decisions on corporate prosecution.
The first of these memos, named after Deputy Attorney General
Eric Holder,
73
was released in 1999 without much fanfare.
74
At that
time, the United States was experiencing unprecedented business
prosperity, and corporate prosecution was hardly en vogue.
75
Within
a short period of time, however, this dramatically changed. In the
years following the issuance of the Holder Memo, a series of corpo-
the impossibility of fitting liberal concepts about responsibility with nonhuman actors.” Id.
at 475.
68
Samuel W. Buell notes that although the rule of entity liability allows virtually all
crimes committed by corporate agents to be imputed to the corporation, the law is not
actually applied in such an aggressive manner: Prosecutors have developed a social prac-
tice of evaluating an institution’s “real responsibility” in determining whether or not to
charge the institution. Buell, supra note 67, at 526; see also Thompson Memo, supra note
20, § IV, at 5 (noting that it may not be appropriate to apply respondeat superior liability
for an employee’s “single isolated act” and that prosecutors “should exercise sound discre-
tion in evaluating the pervasiveness of wrongdoing within a corporation”).
69
See infra note 123 and accompanying text.
70
See generally Khanna, supra note 52 (comparing efficacy of corporate civil and crim-
inal liability and concluding that civil liability can provide more effective deterrence at
lower cost).
71
See Thompson Memo, supra note 20, § IX, at 12–13 (expressing this concern).
72
See id. (describing collateral effects of corporate prosecution).
73
Holder Memo, supra note 19.
74
See Finder & McConnell, supra note 19, at 14 (observing that Holder Memo did not
receive as much attention as later Thompson Memo).
75
See id. (noting that Holder Memo was “drafted in a period of unprecedented
prosperity”).
\\server05\productn\N\NYU\82-5\NYU505.txt unknown Seq: 17 16-OCT-07 14:37
1450 NEW YORK UNIVERSITY LAW REVIEW [Vol. 82:1434
rate accounting scandals occurred, including the notable failures of
Enron and WorldCom.
76
As the facts of these scandals came to light,
it became clear that the corporations’ own aggressive business cul-
tures, not merely the actions of a few bad employees, were in large
part driving the criminality.
77
In response to this wave of business crime, the DOJ reprioritized
the prosecution of corporate entities. The Thompson Memo, the most
significant of the three Deputy Attorney General memos, was
released in early 2003 as part of this renewed DOJ effort.
78
The
Memo noted that prosecutions against individuals could be supple-
mented by the unique benefits that flow from an additional charge
against the corporate entity.
79
It also posited that an indictment
against a corporation could change the culture and behavior of the
entity, as well as that of other corporations in the industry.
80
Industry
peers “are likely to take immediate remedial steps” when another cor-
poration in its respective industry is indicted for criminal conduct, so
that one prosecution can create opportunities for “deterrence on a
massive scale.”
81
To effectuate these purposes, the Thompson Memo laid out a
multifactor test to guide the decision to charge a corporation.
82
Although the DOJ specified that all federal prosecutors were required
76
Id.
77
See John C. Coffee, Jr., What Caused Enron? A Capsule Social and Economic His-
tory of the 1990s, 89 C
ORNELL
L. R
EV
. 269, 270, 281–82 (2004) (arguing “that Enron and
related scandals were neither unique nor idiosyncratic; rather, pervasive problems arose
that undercut existing systems of corporate governance”). See generally B
ETHANY
M
C
L
EAN
& P
ETER
E
LKIND
, T
HE
S
MARTEST
G
UYS IN THE
R
OOM
: T
HE
A
MAZING
R
ISE
AND
S
CANDALOUS
F
ALL OF
E
NRON
(2003) (providing detailed history of Enron scandal
and description of business culture that generated it). Coffee notes, among other explana-
tions for the spate of corporate scandals, that emphasis on earnings and stock price, with
executive compensation tied to success in those metrics, induced managers to engage in
risky behavior. Coffee, supra, at 275.
78
See Carmen Couden, The Thompson Memorandum: A Revised Solution or Just a
Problem?, 30 J. C
ORP
. L. 405, 413 (2005) (“[I]n response to the corporate fraud scandals
. . . Deputy Attorney General Larry D. Thompson issued a revision of the DOJ’s guide-
lines on corporate prosecution.”); Wray & Hur, supra note 23, at 1097 (“The spate of
corporate scandals that began with Enron’s meltdown in 2001 prompted the Bush Admin-
istration to dramatically increase the federal government’s focus on rooting out corporate
fraud . . . .”).
79
Thompson Memo, supra note 20, § I(B), at 1.
80
Id.
81
Id.
82
The factors are:
1. the nature and seriousness of the offense, including the risk of harm to the
public, and applicable policies and priorities, if any, governing the prosecu-
tion of corporations for particular categories of crime;
2. the pervasiveness of wrongdoing within the corporation, including the com-
plicity in, or condonation of, the wrongdoing by corporate management;
\\server05\productn\N\NYU\82-5\NYU505.txt unknown Seq: 18 16-OCT-07 14:37
November 2007] CORPORATE PROSECUTION AGREEMENTS 1451
to use these factors,
83
the Memo was ambiguous about their practical
application. It stated that while the nine factors listed were meant to
be “illustrative of those that should be considered,” they were not
meant to be an exhaustive list.
84
Furthermore, the Memo was silent
on how much weight a prosecutor should put on any individual factor,
stating, without further explanation, that “in some cases one factor
may override all others.”
85
In short, the Thompson Memo balancing
test entrusted a massive amount of discretion to the individual prose-
cutors who would determine whether to employ the New York Central
vicarious liability standard.
In December 2006, the DOJ replaced the Thompson Memo with
the McNulty Memo,
86
which contains two significant modifications
relating to corporate cooperation with criminal investigations. As
noted in the Introduction, the cooperation provisions of the
Thompson Memo produced an enormous outcry: The Memo was crit-
icized by businesses, advocacy organizations, senators, ex-attorneys
general, and even Thompson himself.
87
The McNulty Memo
addresses these criticisms by making two key changes. First, the
McNulty Memo states that prosecutors generally may not consider
whether a corporation is advancing an employee attorneys’ fees in
3. the corporation’s history of similar conduct, including prior criminal, civil,
and regulatory enforcement actions against it;
4. the corporation’s timely and voluntary disclosure of wrongdoing and its
willingness to cooperate in the investigation of its agents, including, if neces-
sary, the waiver of corporate attorney-client and work product protection;
5. the existence and adequacy of the corporation’s compliance program;
6. the corporation’s remedial actions, including any efforts to implement an
effective corporate compliance program or to improve an existing one, to
replace responsible management, to discipline or terminate wrongdoers, to
pay restitution, and to cooperate with the relevant government agencies;
7. collateral consequences, including disproportionate harm to shareholders,
pension holders and employees not proven personally culpable and impact
on the public arising from the prosecution;
8. the adequacy of the prosecution of individuals responsible for the corpora-
tion’s malfeasance;
9. the adequacy of remedies such as civil or regulatory enforcement actions.
Id. § II(A), at 3 (internal cross-references omitted). For an analysis of each factor, see
Couden, supra note 78, at 407–14.
83
U.S. D
EP
TOF
J
USTICE
, C
RIMINAL
R
ESOURCE
M
ANUAL
§ 163 (2005) (“The
Thompson Memorandum sets forth nine factors that federal prosecutors must consider in
determining whether to charge a corporation or other business organization.”); see also
United States v. Stein, 435 F. Supp. 2d 330, 338 (S.D.N.Y. 2006) (noting that, unlike
Holder Memo, Thompson Memo was binding on all federal prosecutors).
84
Thompson Memo, supra note 20, § II(B), at 4.
85
Id.
86
McNulty Memo, supra note 6.
87
See supra notes 4–5 and accompanying text.
\\server05\productn\N\NYU\82-5\NYU505.txt unknown Seq: 19 16-OCT-07 14:37
1452 NEW YORK UNIVERSITY LAW REVIEW [Vol. 82:1434
assessing cooperation.
88
This change addresses a recent constitutional
challenge to the attorneys’ fees aspect of the Thompson Memo.
89
The
second modification relates to prosecutorial requests for waiver of
attorney-client privilege—a highly contentious aspect of the
Thompson Memo.
The McNulty Memo does not ban these waiver requests. Rather,
it restricts their use in three significant ways. First, the Memo clarifies
that such waivers should only be requested when a “legitimate need”
exists.
90
Second, the McNulty Memo states that if the government
makes a request for waiver, the waiver should be “the least intrusive
waiver necessary.”
91
Furthermore, the Memo precludes prosecutors
from considering a corporation’s refusal to release “attorney-client
communications or non-factual attorney work product” in their
charging decision.
92
Third—and most importantly for the present dis-
cussion—the Memo imposes a certain amount of uniformity by
requiring individual prosecutors to vet their waiver decisions with
upper-level DOJ officials.
93
As discussed below, this latter proposal—
vetting by senior DOJ officials—may provide guidance for remedying
threats of abuse in the use of prosecution agreements with
corporations.
94
C. Accounting Fraud and Extreme Collateral Consequences
Although each of the three DOJ memos offered some guidance
for prosecutors faced with the decision of whether or not to prosecute
a corporation, the memos did not—and perhaps could not—tell a
prosecutor how to make a final discretionary determination. In
making these determinations, one concern in particular became para-
mount: the massive collateral consequences to innocent shareholders
and employees that often result from corporate indictment and/or
prosecution. Even in those situations when entity prosecution could
88
Specifically, the McNulty Memo states that prosecutors should not consider a corpo-
ration’s advancement of legal fees as indicative of non-cooperation except in rare cases
where the totality of the circumstances indicates that the corporation’s actions were
intended to impede a government investigation. McNulty Memo, supra note 6,
§ VII(B)(3), at 11–12; see also McNulty Speech, supra note 1 (emphasizing that McNulty
Memo “generally prohibit[s] prosecutors from considering whether a corporation is
advancing attorneys’ fees”).
89
See United States v. Stein, 435 F. Supp. 2d 330, 362–69 (S.D.N.Y. 2006) (holding that
government violated Fifth and Sixth Amendments by causing company to cut off payment
of legal fees to employees).
90
McNulty Memo, supra note 6, § VII(B)(2), at 8–9.
91
Id. § VII(B)(2), at 9.
92
Id. § VII(B)(2), at 10.
93
Id. § VII(B)(2), at 9.
94
See infra Part IV.B.
\\server05\productn\N\NYU\82-5\NYU505.txt unknown Seq: 20 16-OCT-07 14:37
November 2007] CORPORATE PROSECUTION AGREEMENTS 1453
be justified because of a corrupt corporate culture (as was arguably
the case with Enron), prosecutors were rightly concerned with the
negative effects on innocent third parties such as shareholders and
employees. Although each of the DOJ memos explicitly counsels that
prosecutors should consider the issue of collateral consequences, they
provide little guidance on how that interest should be balanced
against the others.
The concern with collateral consequences is especially acute
when dealing with charges related to financial fraud.
95
It has often
been said that no major American financial services institution has
survived criminal indictment.
96
The prosecution of Arthur Andersen
is perhaps the most dramatic recent example of the collateral conse-
quences of prosecuting a financial services company: After indict-
ment for its role in the Enron accounting scandal, more than twenty-
eight thousand Arthur Andersen employees were laid off in the
United States alone.
97
A company like Arthur Andersen could not
survive such a public blow to its reputation and integrity.
The collateral consequences of financial fraud are not limited,
however, to financial services companies. Disastrous collateral conse-
quences can result when any major company that depends on public
reputation—publicly traded companies, in particular—engages in
fraud related to its finances. Criminal charges involving financial
fraud call into question the basic information relayed by the company
about its financial health and prospects—information that various
95
David Pitofsky, the lead prosecutor in the prosecution agreement negotiations with
Computer Associates, believes that a distinction needs to be drawn between prosecutions
of corporations for financial fraud and prosecutions for other kinds of crimes:
You have to draw a distinction between the types of violations.
If it is a Foreign Corrupt Practices Act violation, or an antitrust or an
environmental violation, that’s different than if it is an accounting fraud viola-
tion. The market receives an accounting fraud violation as a black cloud over
the entire company. Investors don’t know what they are buying when they buy
a share of stock of the company.
With an FCPA violation, it doesn’t undermine your confidence in the
entire company, top to bottom. Its [sic] something that can be carved out.
You can see that the company can go forward, that it has good products and
strong finances and that it is worth investing in. But when you are talking
about a securities fraud case, you really have to ask yourself—is this company
a total sham?
Interview with David Pitofsky, supra note 14, at 12.
96
E.g., Ken Brown et al., Called to Account: Indictment of Andersen in Shredding Case
Puts Its Future in Question: Obstruction of Justice Count May Speed the Departure of Cli-
ents and Partners: Firm Calls It ‘Death Penalty, W
ALL
S
T
. J., Mar. 15, 2002, at A1; Monica
Langley & Ian McDonald, Marsh Averts Criminal Case with New CEO, W
ALL
S
T
. J., Oct.
26, 2004, at A1.
97
Finder & McConnell, supra note 19, at 14–15.
\\server05\productn\N\NYU\82-5\NYU505.txt unknown Seq: 21 16-OCT-07 14:37
1454 NEW YORK UNIVERSITY LAW REVIEW [Vol. 82:1434
markets rely upon in evaluating the company.
98
Charges involving
inaccurate financial data send shockwaves through the investing and
creditor communities and often cause the market to lose faith in the
targeted corporation.
99
The heightened stakes of these kinds of offenses thrust a tremen-
dous responsibility upon the government. When confronted with a
corporation that measures poorly against the DOJ memo factors, the
government has to decide not only whether the company’s behavior
merits sanction, but whether it wants to risk putting the company out
of business and inflicting heavy losses on innocent third parties.
100
It is in this context that the use of prosecution agreements has
become so significant. Prosecutors—even when convinced that a
company’s actions merit criminal sanction—have become hesitant to
risk destroying the company by prosecuting it, thereby harming share-
holders and employees. Prosecution agreements provide a solution to
this problem, permitting the imposition of criminal penalties without
the risk of dire collateral consequences.
101
III
C
ORPORATE
V
ULNERABILITY AND THE
S
PECTER OF
P
ROSECUTORIAL
A
BUSE
This Part explores the ramifications of unrestrained prosecutorial
power in the use of prosecution agreements. Part III.A notes the
respective reasons why both a prosecutor and a corporation might
98
Id.
99
See infra notes 104–07 and accompanying text.
100
Deputy Attorney General James Comey has remarked that corporate criminal pros-
ecutions should only be used in cases where the prosecutor is willing to “put down” the
corporation. James Comey, U.S. Deputy Att’y Gen., Statement at Justice Dep’t News
Conference (Sept. 22, 2004) (LexisNexis Media Transcripts). In this vein, then-New York
Attorney General Eliot Spitzer backed off prosecuting Marsh & McLennan when told that
the company “was in an ‘Arthur Andersen situation.’” B
ROOKE
A. M
ASTERS
, S
POILING
FOR A
F
IGHT
: T
HE
R
ISE OF
E
LIOT
S
PITZER
218 (2006).
101
Of course, this particular advantage of prosecution agreements may not be the only
explanation for their increased use. Part of this increase can perhaps be attributed to the
general reprioritization of corporate crime prevention following the accounting scandals of
the early part of the decade. On July 9, 2002, President George W. Bush formed a
Corporate Fraud Task Force, which focused the DOJ and U.S. Attorneys’ Offices on the
issue of corporate crime. See Exec. Order No. 13,271, 3 C.F.R. 245 (2002), reprinted as
amended in 28 U.S.C. § 509 (Supp. IV 2004) (establishing Task Force). At the state level,
attorneys general like Eliot Spitzer reinvigorated efforts to root out fraud. See generally
M
ASTERS
, supra note 100 (highlighting Eliot Spitzer’s campaigns against white collar
fraud). However, while the reallocation of resources aimed at detection and prosecution
of corporate crime certainly explains the attention paid to corporate crime, it does not
explain the increased use of one particular tool: prosecution agreements. See infra notes
118–19 and accompanying text (arguing that powers prosecution agreements offer to pros-
ecutors incentivize their increased use).
\\server05\productn\N\NYU\82-5\NYU505.txt unknown Seq: 22 16-OCT-07 14:37
November 2007] CORPORATE PROSECUTION AGREEMENTS 1455
desire to enter into a prosecution agreement. There is, however, a
bargaining imbalance in these negotiations: Corporations are
uniquely vulnerable to criminal sanction, which shifts power and lev-
erage to the prosecutor. Part III.B addresses the implications of this
bargaining imbalance, including the threat of abuse that results from
one-sided negotiations. I focus in particular on two signs of abuse—
lack of predictability in punishment and prosecutorial overreaching—
as examples of problems that result when prosecutorial discretion is
unchecked.
A. Inequality of Bargaining Position in the Negotiation of
Prosecution Agreements
Prosecution agreements, like other settlements, offer benefits for
all parties. Companies avoid criminal liability; prosecutors reform and
punish while conserving resources. Beneath this apparent mutuality
of benefits, however, lies a distinct power imbalance. Though both
the corporation and the prosecutor have reason to prefer settlement
to prosecution, their interests are not equivalent.
102
A company does
not just want to avoid prosecutionit may need to avoid prosecution
in order to save itself.
Corporations are uniquely vulnerable to criminal prosecution for
a variety of reasons. First, as explained previously, the law of corpo-
rate liability is remarkably broad in scope—once the government has
established criminal conduct by an employee, the corporation is
nearly strictly liable.
103
Corporations thus have great difficulty win-
ning at trial, no matter what precautions they have taken.
Even in the small percentage of cases where a company might
have a promising defense, publicly traded corporations are still tre-
mendously vulnerable to criminal charges.
104
This is primarily due to
corporate reliance on public perception—the necessity of preserving
102
Prosecutors may also want to avoid the collateral consequences of corporate prose-
cution—but not to the same extent as the shareholders and employees of a targeted com-
pany. Prosecutors must accept that their job may sometimes require the use of the
ultimate penalty against a corporate offender, despite the collateral consequences. See
Thompson Memo, supra note 20, § IX(B), at 12 (“[T]he mere existence of [collateral con-
sequences] is not sufficient to preclude prosecution of the corporation.”).
103
See White, supra note 23, at 817 (“[T]he sweep of corporate criminal liability could
hardly be broader. . . . It is essentially absolute liability.”); supra Part II.A.
104
See Andrew Weissmann with David Newman, Rethinking Criminal Corporate Lia-
bility, 82 I
ND
. L.J. 411, 426 (2007) (describing “devastating consequences” of criminal
indictment of corporation); Richard A. Epstein, Op-Ed, The Deferred Prosecution Racket,
W
ALL
S
T
. J., Nov. 28, 2006, at A14 (stating that even companies that believe they have
reasonable defenses at trial are “helpless to protect [themselves],” since indictment can be
very damaging).
\\server05\productn\N\NYU\82-5\NYU505.txt unknown Seq: 23 16-OCT-07 14:37
1456 NEW YORK UNIVERSITY LAW REVIEW [Vol. 82:1434
“the reputation of a corporation in the eyes of third parties.”
105
As a
result, mere indictment can put a company in a tremendously vulner-
able position: Stock prices plummet, lines of credit dry up, and clients
are scared off.
106
Without the promise of a prosecution agreement, a
company may not be able to “avoid[ ] the paralysis that can grip an
indicted corporation unsure of the impending resolution of its legal
problems.”
107
These harms—which can result from a mere charge,
regardless of the result at trial—can destroy a business entity, as
occurred with Arthur Andersen.
108
The effective result of this vulnerability to mere indictment, not
just conviction, is that corporations cannot typically risk going to
trial.
109
This is a tremendous weakness. Prosecutors enjoy wide dis-
cretion regarding whom they charge and what crimes they allege—
decisions which are generally unreviewable.
110
The trial by jury is the
105
Greenblum, supra note 9, at 1887 & n.167. This concern is more pressing for corpo-
rations than for individuals. Id. at 1887, 1895 (“The adverse publicity and collateral conse-
quences of a conviction are tantamount to a death penalty for corporations, but not for
individuals.”).
106
See id. at 1886 (“The adverse publicity that accompanies a prosecution can devastate
a corporation, particularly one that relies heavily on its reputation in the marketplace,
because of the effect on relationships with customers, creditors, and the public at large.”
(citation omitted)); Interview with David Pitofsky, supra note 14, at 11 (“[U]pon the
announcement of a criminal investigation, companies regularly lose half of their market
value. If the price remains depressed long enough, the capital markets dry up, the ability
to hire quality people dries up. The company’s oxygen supply is cut off.”).
107
Greenblum, supra note 9, at 1887.
108
The Supreme Court overturned the Arthur Andersen conviction on May 31, 2005.
Arthur Andersen LLP v. United States, 544 U.S. 696, 698 (2005) (“We hold that the jury
instructions failed to convey properly the elements of a ‘corrup[t] persua[sion]’ conviction
under § 1512(b), and therefore reverse.” (alteration in original) (quoting 18 U.S.C.
§ 1512(b) (2000 & Supp. IV 2004))). The decision proved to be too little, too late, as the
indictment itself had effectively driven Arthur Andersen out of business. Finder &
McConnell, supra note 19, at 14–15 & n.66.
It is commonly assumed that the fate of Arthur Andersen—collapse following indict-
ment—would be shared by many other companies were they to face similar indictment.
See Greenblum, supra note 9, at 1888–89 (“[Arthur Andersen] suggests the potentially
catastrophic result that may await at trial.”); Weissmann, supra note 104, at 426 (noting
that indictment “risks the market imposing what is in effect a corporate death penalty”);
Wray & Hur, supra note 23, at 1097 (noting that “indictment often amounts to a virtual
death sentence for business entities”). This is believed to be true even though Andersen
was a partnership and not a publicly traded corporation. Id. at 1097 (noting that Andersen
case “sent a clear and unmistakable message to Corporate America in general”). As the
number of non-deferred prosecutions of publicly traded companies following the collapse
of Andersen has been minimal, there is very little empirical support for this claim. Regard-
less, an evaluation of this widespread assumption is beyond the scope of this Note.
109
Weissmann, supra note 104, at 426 (“[C]orporations as a practical matter can rarely
afford to take criminal cases to trial . . . .”).
110
See, e.g., Wayte v. United States, 470 U.S. 598, 607 (1985) (“In our criminal justice
system, the Government retains ‘broad discretion’ as to whom to prosecute.”);
Bordenkircher v. Hayes, 434 U.S. 357, 364 (1978) (“[S]o long as the prosecutor has prob-
\\server05\productn\N\NYU\82-5\NYU505.txt unknown Seq: 24 16-OCT-07 14:37
November 2007] CORPORATE PROSECUTION AGREEMENTS 1457
principal way we test prosecutorial discretion in our criminal justice
system. It is the primary means for checking overly aggressive
prosecutorial behavior.
111
Without the threat of trial, however, there
is no assurance that the prosecutor is acting in a judicious manner.
B. The Specter of Abuse
The legal and reputational vulnerabilities detailed above make
corporations uniquely weak negotiators in the criminal context. Since
corporations cannot run the risk of going to trial, their choice to
accept a deferred prosecution agreement is not really a choice at all.
112
Given this kind of leverage, prosecutors can negotiate overwhelmingly
favorable prosecution agreements. The benefits that flow to a prose-
cutor as a result of this leverage are evident from the terms of the
agreements: enormous financial penalties, significant internal busi-
able cause to believe that the accused committed an offense defined by statute, the deci-
sion whether or not to prosecute, and what charge to file or bring before a grand jury,
generally rests entirely in his discretion.”); United States v. Dotterweich, 320 U.S. 277, 285
(1943) (“[T]he good sense of prosecutors . . . must be trusted.”); Stolt-Nielsen, S.A. v.
United States, 442 F.3d 177, 183 (3d Cir. 2006) (noting that executive branch, through its
prosecutors, “has exclusive authority and absolute discretion to decide whether to prose-
cute a case” (citing United States v. Nixon, 418 U.S. 683, 693 (1974))). See generally James
Vorenberg, Decent Restraint of Prosecutorial Power, 94 H
ARV
. L. R
EV
. 1521 (1981) (exam-
ining pervasive power of prosecutors in U.S. criminal justice system). The Supreme Court
has identified two separate bases for why courts give prosecutors broad deference in mat-
ters of prosecution. First, because prosecution is an executive act aimed at fulfilling the
President’s constitutional obligation to “take Care that the Laws be faithfully executed,”
U.S. C
ONST
. art. II, § 3, cl. 4, judicial deference helps fulfill separation of powers principles.
United States v. Armstrong, 517 U.S. 456, 464 (1996) (“[Prosecutors help the President]
discharge his constitutional responsibility to take Care that the Laws be faithfully exe-
cuted. As a result, [t]he presumption of regularity supports their prosecutorial decisions
and, in the absence of clear evidence to the contrary, courts presume that they have prop-
erly discharged their official duties.” (alteration in original) (internal quotation marks and
citations omitted)). Second, courts’ lack of competence in matters of prosecutorial discre-
tion militate against intervention. Id. at 465 (“Judicial deference to the decisions of [prose-
cutors] rests in part on an assessment of the relative competence of prosecutors and
courts.”).
111
The Supreme Court has noted the role that a jury trial plays in checking aggressive
prosecutorial behavior: “The purpose of a jury is to guard against the exercise of arbitrary
power—to make available the commonsense judgment of the community as a hedge
against the overzealous or mistaken prosecutor and in preference to the professional or
perhaps overconditioned or biased response of a judge.” Taylor v. Louisiana, 419 U.S. 522,
530 (1975) (citing Duncan v. Louisiana, 391 U.S. 145, 155–56 (1968)). Professor Lisa Kern
Griffin notes that juries have provided a check against prosecutorial overreaching in a
number of recent, high-profile white collar cases. Griffin, supra note 23, at 380 & n.357.
Each of her examples, however, concerns a charge against an individual, not a corporate
entity. As detailed in this Note, corporations cannot typically risk indictment or trial, and
thus cannot test the merits of the prosecution’s case by bringing their cases before a jury.
112
See Greenblum, supra note 9, at 1885, 1895 (“The corporate offender’s unique vul-
nerability to adverse publicity and collateral consequences . . . calls into question whether
the choice to enter into deferral is really a choice at all.”).
\\server05\productn\N\NYU\82-5\NYU505.txt unknown Seq: 25 16-OCT-07 14:37
1458 NEW YORK UNIVERSITY LAW REVIEW [Vol. 82:1434
ness reforms, and cooperation in pursuing the corporation’s individu-
ally culpable employees and directors.
113
This last point—assistance
in the pursuit of individuals—is of particular importance to resource-
deficient prosecutors. White collar prosecutions are tremendously dif-
ficult to conduct. The trials often depend on complex financial
records and complicated regulatory schemes
114
—material which may
test the comprehension of a typical jury.
115
The offenses typically take
place in large organizations where decisionmaking is shared among
boards of directors, executives, mid-level managers, and ground-level
employees, making it difficult to identify who should be held respon-
sible for the alleged criminal activity.
116
Furthermore, government
prosecutors often have to tangle with well-financed defendants
capable of hiring sophisticated law firms that can match government
resources.
117
For all of these reasons, corporate cooperation through
prosecution agreements—admitting liability, identifying perpetrators
of the criminal conduct, and occasionally waiving privilege to internal
documents and investigations—can be invaluable in prosecuting a
case against the individuals.
In light of these benefits, one might ask why a prosecutor would
not demand a prosecution agreement. After all, a prosecution agree-
ment removes the threat of corporate collapse, saves resources, and
offers a relatively one-sided negotiation where the prosecutor can ask
for almost anything, including cooperation in prosecuting individual
offenders.
It is precisely this accumulation of unchecked power that is dis-
concerting. Prosecutors have tremendous incentives to use prosecu-
113
See supra Part I.B.
114
Andrew Weissmann & Joshua A. Block, White-Collar Defendants and White-Collar
Crimes, 116 Y
ALE
L.J. P
OCKET
P
ART
286, 290 n.18 (2007), http://thepocketpart.org/2007/
02/21/weissmann_block.html (“White-collar prosecutions are notoriously difficult to
pursue successfully because they depend on complex financial records and often arcane
regulatory schemes.”).
115
Professor Stuart Green notes that understanding the processes behind white collar
crime often requires sophisticated knowledge of a variety of complex subjects, including,
inter alia, finance, management, and accounting. Stuart P. Green, Moral Ambiguity in
White Collar Criminal Law, 18 N
OTRE
D
AME
J.L. E
THICS
& P
UB
. P
OL
Y
501, 508 (2004).
116
Id. at 510.
117
See Elizabeth Szockyj, Imprisoning White-Collar Criminals?, 23 S. I
LL
. U. L.J. 485,
487–88 (1999) (“Criminologists have long lamented the resources white-collar criminals
have at their disposal: adroit legal counsel, political connections, social legitimacy, alterna-
tive enforcement paths (civil and regulatory routes), and finances that allow them to out-
spend prosecutors.” (citations omitted)); Weissman & Block, supra note 114, at 290 n.18
(“[W]hite collar defendants are often represented by skilled and well-financed
attorneys.”).
\\server05\productn\N\NYU\82-5\NYU505.txt unknown Seq: 26 16-OCT-07 14:37
November 2007] CORPORATE PROSECUTION AGREEMENTS 1459
tion agreements: The benefits are often too great to refuse.
118
They
offer a means for prosecutors to exploit the vulnerabilities of public
corporations—in particular their dependence on reputation and
public perception for healthy relationships with investors, creditors,
and clients
119
—as a means to attack corporate crime. Corporations
wary of Arthur Andersen’s fate, and cognizant of New York Central’s
unfavorable liability rule—have little choice but to agree to the prose-
cutor’s demands.
One might argue that there is nothing wrong with this situation:
The reputational concerns of corporations are being leveraged against
them in the legitimate pursuit of ferreting out crime. To a certain
extent, it is satisfying that the same motives that led to the recent
wave of accounting fraud—the desire to craft a strong public image of
financial health—are being leveraged against corporations in an effort
to clean up criminal behavior. The concern, however, is not with the
efforts to stop corporate crime, but rather with the bargaining and
settlement dynamic itself. When the corporation is unwilling to risk
trial and incapable of defending itself in any case, there is no assur-
ance that the prosecutor is using her discretion wisely. It is in this
exploitation of the corporation’s unique vulnerabilities that one
begins to see the first signs of abuse. The two most obvious indica-
tions of the abuse are the lack of predictability and prosecutorial over-
reaching in various agreements.
Lack of Predictability: The first sign of abuse is that there is little
predictability in the terms of prosecution agreements. In the corpo-
rate criminal context, like conduct often does not receive like punish-
ment. Conduct that would merit a declination from one prosecutor
might lead to a prosecution agreement with another prosecutor. To
take a recent example, a billion dollar misreporting scheme received a
prosecutorial declination from one U.S. Attorney’s Office, while a
five-figure bribery attempt produced a tremendously punitive
deferred prosecution agreement from a different U.S. Attorney’s
Office.
120
The difference between deferred prosecution agreements
118
See Richard S. Gruner, Three Painful Lessons: Corporate Experience with Deferred
Prosecution Agreements, in C
ORPORATE
C
OMPLIANCE
I
NSTITUTE
2006, at 61, 65–67 (PLI
Corp. Law & Practice, Course Handbook Series No. 891761, 2006) (noting that prosecu-
tion agreements make “the threat of corporate criminal liability more palatable than if a
full fledged prosecution were the federal authorities’ only choice”).
119
Interview with David Pitofsky, supra note 14, at 11 (“[U]pon the announcement of a
criminal investigation, companies regularly lose half of their market value. If the price
remains depressed long enough, the capital markets dry up, the ability to hire quality
people dries up. The company’s oxygen supply is cut off.”).
120
Comparing the facts surrounding criminal investigations is something like comparing
apples and oranges. However, there is still observable inconsistency. F. Joseph Warin and
\\server05\productn\N\NYU\82-5\NYU505.txt unknown Seq: 27 16-OCT-07 14:37
1460 NEW YORK UNIVERSITY LAW REVIEW [Vol. 82:1434
and non-prosecution agreements has largely disappeared: The terms
of non-prosecution agreements, which are thought to convey a lower
degree of culpability than deferred prosecution agreements, actually
can be as harsh as their deferred counterparts.
121
Much of this, of
course, is the result of the language in the Holder, Thompson, and
McNulty Memos: They give broad discretion to prosecutors to deter-
mine whether or not to file criminal charges against a corporation,
resulting in almost total leeway in crafting such agreements.
122
A cor-
poration under investigation might compare its behavior with that of
past corporations, in a hope that analogous criminality will receive
analogous treatment. The prosecutor, however, is not required to
follow any kind of precedent and has virtually unlimited discretion in
deciding what kind of action to take.
This lack of predictability has two implications. First, unpredict-
ability prevents corporate planning. If a corporation has no clear
sense of what employee crimes will be imputed to the entity or what
punishment those crimes might produce, the corporation will have dif-
ficulty properly allocating its resources. Corporations will be unable
to predict, ex ante, what compliance measures prosecutors will con-
sider adequate ex post, which in turn “breed[s] over deterrence and
risk aversion, both of which increase the company’s (and society’s)
costs.”
123
Deferred and non-prosecution agreements further exacer-
bate this tendency toward overdeterrence: Onlooker corporations
Peter E. Jaffe offer the following comparison of two 2005 prosecutorial actions, the Mon-
santo Deferred Prosecution Agreement and the declination to prosecute Shell Oil:
So in Shell and Monsanto we have two blue-chip, highly regarded public com-
panies: each discovered a violation of federal law; each immediately initiated
an internal investigation and promptly self-reported to federal authorities who,
in each instance, had theretofore been unaware of the conduct; each cooper-
ated fully with the investigations of both the DOJ and the SEC; and each sub-
stantially remedied its respective compliance program. Yet one corporation
walked away with the disconcerting prospect of conducting 36 months of busi-
ness under the shadow of a deferred criminal information and a corporate
monitor, while the other was let off with a good talking to. Oh, and did we
mention that Shell, the one admonished to “go forth and sin no more,”
admitted to a misreporting scheme that allegedly cost investors billions of dol-
lars, while Monsanto, the one with the hammer-shaped cloud hanging over its
head, admitted to a failed five-figure bribery attempt that, in the end, cost no
one but itself?
F. Joseph Warin & Peter E. Jaffe, The Deferred-Prosecution Jigsaw Puzzle: A Modest Pro-
posal for Reform, A
NDREWS
L
ITIG
. R
EP
.: W
HITE
C
OLLAR
C
RIME
, Sept. 2005, at 1, 1 (foot-
note omitted).
121
See supra note 18 and accompanying text.
122
See supra notes 82–85 and accompanying text.
123
Miriam H. Baer, Insuring Corporate Crime, 83 I
ND
. L.J. (forthcoming 2008) (manu-
script at 22), available at http://lsr.nellco.org/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=1050&context=
nyu/plltwp.
\\server05\productn\N\NYU\82-5\NYU505.txt unknown Seq: 28 16-OCT-07 14:37
November 2007] CORPORATE PROSECUTION AGREEMENTS 1461
notice the drastic penalties which accompany these agreements, giving
the agreements a deterrent power that belies their relatively small
number.
124
Corporations may respond to these vague deterrents by
erring on the side of caution, which could result in the overdeterrence
of aggressive but legitimate business practices.
125
Second, unpredictability violates basic notions of fairness. When
similar offenses give rise to widely disparate punishments, a defendant
has good reason to feel that the system is unjust. Our legal system has
faced this issue before: In 1984, Congress reformed the Federal Sen-
tencing Guidelines to address the disparities in punishment that
resulted from the wide sentencing discretion enjoyed by federal
judges.
126
With the development of prosecution agreements, however,
the power to punish corporations has shifted from judges to prosecu-
tors. These prosecutors, like federal judges prior to 1984, have no
guidelines to cabin their discretion.
Prosecutorial Overreaching: The second indication of abuse
comes from the quixotic nature of some terms in the agreements.
Some of the more bizarre conditions have already been addressed—
the requirement to create sixteen hundred jobs in the WorldCom
Agreement,
127
or the provision to endow a chair in legal ethics in the
Bristol-Meyers Squibb Agreement.
128
These examples are, admit-
tedly, still quite unusual. The infrequency of these unusual terms is
likely due to the restraint of the prosecutors that author the agree-
ments: The majority of these agreements have been negotiated by the
DOJ and U.S. Attorneys’ Offices, organizations generally known for
their integrity and restraint. Of the two aforementioned bizarre con-
ditions, only one of the two—the endowed chair of ethics—was
authored by a federal prosecutor, and that term was allegedly pro-
posed by the defense counsel, not the government.
129
Integrity, however, can only go so far: The massive, unfettered
power that prosecution agreements offer to prosecutors ushers in the
possibility of these kinds of bizarre conditions. While such conditions
124
Id. at 1.
125
See id. (arguing that corporations will overpay to avoid collateral consequences of
criminal indictment).
126
See Adam Lamparello, Implementing the “Heartland Departure” in a Post-Booker
World, 32 A
M
. J. C
RIM
. L. 133, 152–54 (2005) (noting that concerns with sentencing dispar-
ities motivated creation of guidelines).
127
See supra note 44 and accompanying text.
128
See supra note 45 and accompanying text.
129
The WorldCom Agreement, which featured the job-creation provision, was negoti-
ated by the Attorney General of Oklahoma, not the DOJ. Finder & McConnell, supra
note 19, at 36. The Bristol-Meyers Squibb Agreement was negotiated by the U.S.
Attorney’s Office in New Jersey. See supra note 45.
\\server05\productn\N\NYU\82-5\NYU505.txt unknown Seq: 29 16-OCT-07 14:37
1462 NEW YORK UNIVERSITY LAW REVIEW [Vol. 82:1434
are fairly innocuous at present, they could become more offensive in
the future. Further, it is disturbing to see these conditions coming
from government prosecutors, individuals who are trained in prosecu-
tion, not corporate regulation.
130
Mary Jo White, the former U.S.
Attorney for the Southern District of New York, has claimed that
prosecutors are transforming into “super regulators”—capable of
being proactive in any direction they please.
131
If a prosecutor can
require the creation of jobs in the local community, or the endowment
of a chair at a favored law school, what limits exist—especially when a
corporation under threat of indictment will do almost anything to sat-
isfy the government?
132
As one commentator has said, prosecutors
are “starting to possess something close to absolute power.”
133
A
solution that limits this discretion is sorely needed.
IV
W
HAT
C
AN
B
E
D
ONE
?
This Part reviews potential solutions to the threat of prosecutorial
abuse. Part IV.A lays out two solutions suggested in the scholarship
that address the imbalance in bargaining leverage between corpora-
tions and prosecutors and examines their weaknesses. Part IV.B pro-
poses an alternate solution. Rather than seeking to alter the
underlying law or the enforceability of the agreements, this solution
restrains prosecutorial discretion by centralizing the review of prose-
cution agreements in the office of the Deputy Attorney General.
Such a framework, similar to that employed by the McNulty Memo
with regard to waivers of attorney-client privilege, would impose uni-
formity and consistency on the choices of individual prosecutors,
addressing the problem of abuse noted in Part III. Centralized over-
sight would address the concerns identified in Part III by ensuring
consistency and restraining overreaching by individual prosecutors.
A. Proposed Fixes
Armed with an easy-to-satisfy legal standard and near limitless
discretion, the prosecutor who desires to impose corporate criminal
130
Professor Coffee argues that acts of regulation are beyond the “competence or enti-
tlement” of prosecutors. See supra note 38.
131
White, supra note 23, at 818.
132
A company’s objective, as described in the KPMG case, was “to be able to say at the
right time with the right audience, we’re in full compliance with the Thompson Guide-
lines.” United States v. Stein, 435 F. Supp. 2d 330, 348 (S.D.N.Y. 2006) (internal quotation
marks omitted).
133
Coffee, supra note 38, at 13 (“[T]he deeper problem lies in the danger that power
corrupts and that prosecutors are starting to possess something close to absolute power.”).
\\server05\productn\N\NYU\82-5\NYU505.txt unknown Seq: 30 16-OCT-07 14:37
November 2007] CORPORATE PROSECUTION AGREEMENTS 1463
liability is not significantly restrained by the law. Prosecutors do not
need to push the envelope in order to threaten liability against corpo-
rate entities: The stigma of criminal liability is so powerful, yet
remarkably easy to apply.
Commentators have proposed two solutions to address the bar-
gaining imbalance between corporations and prosecutors. The first
proposed solution—perhaps both the cleanest and the least likely to
occur—is simply to change the law of vicarious corporate liability.
The foundation of prosecution agreements is the near absolute lia-
bility standard of New York Central coupled with the corporation’s
inability to go to trial. Scholars and practitioners have long criticized
the scope of corporate criminal liability.
134
Some have argued that
New York Central was a wrong turn from which the law never recov-
ered.
135
Andrew Weissman, ex-director of the Enron Task Force, has
argued that before charging a corporation with a crime, the govern-
ment should have to bear the burden of establishing that the corpora-
tion failed to have reasonably effective policies and procedures to
prevent the conduct, a standard which would mirror Supreme Court
developments in corporate civil liability.
136
Weissman argues that
adding this new element to the black letter law of liability would
effectively separate the blameworthy corporations from the non-
blameworthy corporations by preventing prosecutors from threat-
ening corporate charges against companies with satisfactory
compliance programs.
137
There is merit to this suggestion. At the base of all prosecution
agreements is the remarkable power granted by the New York Central
standard—a long term solution, therefore, may need to address the
standard itself. Such a proposal, however, would represent a radical
shift in nearly one hundred years of jurisprudence. This is not to say
that such a change would be impossible—the McNulty Memo, after
all, was the result of a massive outcry over what was perceived as
prosecutorial abuse stemming from the Thompson Memo.
138
If the
use of prosecution agreements continues at the current breathtaking
pace, the courts and Congress might feel the need to step in. Congress
has already shown itself willing to intervene in issues related to
134
See, e.g., White, supra note 23, at 817 (stating “the sweep of corporate criminal lia-
bility could hardly be broader”).
135
See Buell, supra note 67, at 474, 478 (noting that enterprise liability had “a weak
start nearly a century ago when common law courts . . . imported respondeat superior
liability from tort law into the criminal law” and that this decision was “a wrong turn for
the criminal law”).
136
Weissman, supra note 104, at 412–13.
137
Id. at 414–15.
138
See supra notes 4–6 and accompanying text.
\\server05\productn\N\NYU\82-5\NYU505.txt unknown Seq: 31 16-OCT-07 14:37
1464 NEW YORK UNIVERSITY LAW REVIEW [Vol. 82:1434
prosecutorial discretion in corporate charging decisions.
139
Perhaps
that desire can evolve into a willingness to reassess the basic black
letter law.
A second proposed solution is to require judicial review of prose-
cution agreements. Most corporations agree to terms whereby the
prosecutor retains the right to determine whether breach has
occurred.
140
If the corporation breaches, the agreement is revoked
and the corporation will be subject to prosecution. However, corpora-
tions are probably unwilling to demand such judicial review them-
selves. The corporation has signed the agreement because it wants to
avoid prosecution and trial, and the agreement, even if harsh, satisfies
this core concern. With the power to determine whether the agree-
ment has been breached, the prosecutor can effectively play judge and
jury over the corporation’s criminal conduct.
141
While there are some
instances where prosecution agreements permit judicial review of
determinations of breach, these agreements are the exception rather
than the rule.
142
In light of this prosecutorial power, some commentators have
pondered methods for imposing judicial review over the issue of
breach, regardless of the terms of the contract.
143
Judicial review of
breach would no doubt offer some measure of security to the corpora-
tions that sign prosecution agreements. The threat of unilateral revo-
cation has exacerbated the leverage exercised by prosecutors—
companies such as KPMG have been pressured to cooperate
throughout the deferral period, knowing that the government would
be the sole arbiter of whether the terms of the agreement had been
met.
144
139
Browning, supra note 5 (“[T]he departing chairman of the Senate Judiciary
Committee proposed legislation yesterday calling for a rollback of the tactics adopted by
federal prosecutors to combat corporate wrongdoing after the Enron collapse.”).
140
See, e.g., OMI DPA, supra note 25, para. 15. Since prosecution agreements are pri-
vate contractual agreements, it is not clear that judicial review could start any earlier than
the occurrence of breach. See Greenblum, supra note 9, at 1898–99 (noting difficulties of
judicial involvement in negotiation phase).
141
See Greenblum, supra note 9, at 1864 (“Deferral is a powerful prosecutorial tool
because it is negotiated and implemented exclusively by the prosecutor.”).
142
See Warin & Jaffe, supra note 120, at 4 & n.25 (“[I]n those cases where the District
Court does not agree with the DOJ’s breach assessment, a policy of pre-indictment judicial
intervention would save everyone’s time and resources.”).
143
Benjamin Greenblum, for example, argues that judges should be permitted to inter-
vene during the implementation of the deferral terms, which would bring judicial involve-
ment into the definition of breach. This intervention, argues Greenblum, would place an
outer boundary on the “sole discretion” exercised by prosecutors and thus ensure that the
deferral mechanism is not abused. Greenblum, supra note 9, at 1899–1903.
144
See United States v. Stein, 435 F. Supp. 2d 330, 350 (S.D.N.Y. 2006) (noting that if
KPMG did not comply with demands for cooperation, “it will be open to the risk that the
\\server05\productn\N\NYU\82-5\NYU505.txt unknown Seq: 32 16-OCT-07 14:37
November 2007] CORPORATE PROSECUTION AGREEMENTS 1465
It is worth noting, however, that neither the DOJ nor any U.S.
Attorney’s Office has ever revoked a prosecution agreement. While
judicial review over breach of the agreement would be a positive step
for corporations, it would not change the underlying issue of bar-
gaining leverage or prosecutorial discretion. Prosecutors would still
be free to demand almost anything they desire. Moreover, if breach
were to be determined by a judge rather than a prosecutor, one might
expect prosecutors to ask for more detailed agreements. Certain
terms, such as “cooperation,” are currently kept vague—in no small
part because the prosecutor knows he or she reserves the right to
interpret the meaning of “cooperation” and thus determine breach. If
that were not the case, prosecutors would likely respond by crafting
agreements which would more explicitly detail their demands.
The two solutions presented offer limited assistance to a corpora-
tion facing an aggressive prosecutor. The reformation of black letter
law would indeed redistribute the negotiating leverage, but this shift
in jurisprudence is unlikely to occur. Imposing judicial review of
breach has the opposite problem—it may indeed become a feasible
option, but it still does not substantially alter the relationship between
prosecutor and defendant. A more effective solution will have to mit-
igate the bargaining imbalance by limiting the scope of prosecutorial
discretion.
B. Expanding the McNulty Solution
The concerns over the Thompson Memo’s treatment of coopera-
tion, particularly with regard to attorneys’ fees and privilege waiver,
found a remedy in the political sphere. The DOJ responded to pres-
sure—some political, some legal—and issued the McNulty Memo.
145
The legal community decided that these bargaining imbalances were
unacceptable, and addressed it as a matter of policy.
government will declare that KPMG breached [the deferred prosecution agreement] and
prosecute the criminal information to verdict”). In the KPMG prosecution agreement, the
government retained the “sole discretion” to determine whether the company had violated
any of the provisions, including the requirement of cooperation. KPMG DPA, supra note
18, para. 12.
145
This sort of solution was appropriate. The determination of prosecutorial priorities
and the allocation of prosecutorial resources are best determined by individuals account-
able to the public because issues of prosecution are typically questions of politics. Ross E.
Wiener, Inter-branch Appointments After the Independent Counsel: Court Appointment of
United States Attorneys, 86 M
INN
. L. R
EV
. 363, 427 (2001) (noting that prosecutor’s
appointment is “intrinsically a political decision” and that “[s]electing a U.S. Attorney
requires making political judgments about what a district’s prosecutorial priorities should
be and who is best suited to realize those goals”). Courts lack the tools to guide prosecu-
tors’ discretion when they are operating within the boundaries of the law. Prosecutorial
discretion is virtually unfettered. See supra note 110 and accompanying text.
\\server05\productn\N\NYU\82-5\NYU505.txt unknown Seq: 33 16-OCT-07 14:37
1466 NEW YORK UNIVERSITY LAW REVIEW [Vol. 82:1434
The McNulty Memo solution may offer a blueprint for addressing
concerns relating to the accumulation of prosecutorial power high-
lighted in this Note. The McNulty solution requires consultation with
senior attorneys in the DOJ before waiver requests can be made. If a
prosecutor wants access to communications between attorney and
client, the local United States Attorney must get approval from the
Deputy Attorney General.
146
Without explicit permission there can
be no request for waiver.
Some critics of the McNulty Memo have argued that these modi-
fications represent only a “modest improvement.”
147
On the contrary,
I believe that these changes will prove to be significant. On several
prior occasions, the DOJ has sought to constrain prosecutorial discre-
tion by requiring the approval of the Deputy Attorney General, and
this procedural hurdle has been largely effective. Procedures under
the Foreign Intelligence Surveillance Act (FISA)
148
are an example:
FISA warrants, like waiver requests under the McNulty Memo, can
only be issued after approval from either the Attorney General, the
Deputy Attorney General, or the Assistant Attorney General for
National Security.
149
While FISA court proceedings have been criti-
cized as rubber-stamp affairs,
150
various post-9/11 inquiries revealed
DOJ’s internal vetting policies as “much more demanding than out-
siders had imagined.”
151
Centralized review has had a similar effect in
regard to the Economic Espionage Act, a statute that criminalizes
theft of trade secrets and other forms of proprietary information.
152
The Act restrains prosecutorial discretion by mandating centralized
146
McNulty Memo, supra note 6, § VII, at 2; McNulty Speech, supra note 1.
147
See Martha Neil, Thompson Memo Changes Not Enough, ABA Says, A.B.A. J.
E
R
EPORT
, Dec. 15, 2006, http://www.abanet.org/journal/ereport/d15specter.html (quoting
ABA President Karen J. Mathis calling McNulty Memo “modest improvement” and
stating that changes do not go far enough).
148
Originally enacted as the Foreign Intelligence Surveillance Act of 1978, Pub. L. No.
95-511, 92 Stat. 1783 (codified as amended at 50 U.S.C. §§ 1801–1863).
149
Matthew R. Hall, Constitutional Regulation of National Security Investigation: Mini-
mizing the Use of Unrelated Evidence, 41 W
AKE
F
OREST
L. R
EV
. 61, 84 (2006) (citing 50
U.S.C. § 1801(g) (2000) (amended 2006)); see also 50 U.S.C.A. § 1801(g) (West Supp.
2007) (adding Assistant Attorney General for National Security to list of those who may
approve FISA applications).
150
Laura K. Donohue, Anglo-American Privacy and Surveillance, 96 J. C
RIM
. L. &
C
RIMINOLOGY
1059, 1097 (2006) (“[A] legitimate question could be raised as to whether
the court merely serves as a rubber stamp function.”); Stephen J. Schulhofer, The New
World of Foreign Intelligence Surveillance, 17 S
TAN
. L. & P
OL
Y
R
EV
. 531, 535 (2006)
(“[C]ivil liberties groups understandably viewed the FISA Court as little more than a
rubber stamp.”).
151
Schulhofer, supra note 150, at 535.
152
See generally James M. Fischer, Note, An Analysis of the Economic Espionage Act of
1996, 25 S
ETON
H
ALL
L
EGIS
. J. 239 (2001).
\\server05\productn\N\NYU\82-5\NYU505.txt unknown Seq: 34 16-OCT-07 14:37
November 2007] CORPORATE PROSECUTION AGREEMENTS 1467
DOJ approval, which, according to commentators, has resulted in a
lower incidence of prosecution.
153
These results should not be surprising, for two key reasons. First,
the Deputy Attorney General is a single individual with limited
resources and time. Naturally, any approval process that requires the
imprimatur of a single individual will be more restrictive than one that
allows decentralized discretion. Second, and perhaps more impor-
tantly, the Deputy Attorney General is charged with “providing
overall supervision and direction to all the organizational units of the
[DOJ].”
154
Funneling decisionmaking through a figure with such
responsibility will be of particular import where, as with prosecution
agreements, the unfettered discretion of individual prosecutors is part
of the problem.
Constraining prosecutorial discretion will begin to rectify the bar-
gaining imbalance that exists in crafting the terms of prosecution
agreements. While the principal reason prosecution agreements can
be abused is the expansive nature of vicarious liability law and corpo-
rate vulnerability to bad publicity—two factors that likely will not
change—the potential for abuse is exacerbated by prosecutors’ near
limitless discretion. An approval process akin to that required in the
McNulty Memo could address both of the concerns identified above.
Lack of Predictability: As discussed in Part III.B, there is little
standardization in the penalties negotiated in prosecution agree-
ments,
155
which can result in unfairness and overdeterrence of legiti-
mate employee behavior. The Deputy Attorney General’s approval
of penalties could help remedy these problems. That office could pro-
vide centralized review, use past agreements as rough precedent, and
ensure that penalties are proportionate to the misconduct.
153
See Peter E. Calamari, Protection of Confidential Business Information, in
C
ORPORATE
R
AIDING
2001, at 35, 76 (PLI Corp. Law & Practice, Course Handbook Series
No. B0-00VS, 2001) (“[P]rosecutions are likely to be few and far between in the short term.
The Attorney General has stated that, until October 2001, any prosecution under the
Espionage Act will require the personal approval of the Attorney General, the Deputy
Attorney General, or the Assistant Attorney General for the Criminal Division.”); D.
Peter Harvey, IP Maintenance: Protecting Intellectual Property Assets Through Registra-
tion, Proper Use and Contractual Provisions, in P
ROTECTING
Y
OUR
I
NTELLECTUAL
P
ROPERTY
A
SSETS
2002, at 33, 77 (PLI Patents, Copyrights, Trademarks, & Literary Prop-
erty, Course Handbook Series No. G0-0120, 2002) (“Because the Justice Department has
required the personal approval of the Attorney General, the Deputy Attorney General or
the Assistant Attorney General for the Criminal Division before filing a charge under the
[Economic Espionage Act of 1996], only a relatively modest number of prosecutions under
the Act have taken place.”).
154
Office of the Deputy Attorney General, United States Department of Justice, http://
www.usdoj.gov/dag/index.html (last visited June 16, 2007).
155
See supra notes 18, 120.
\\server05\productn\N\NYU\82-5\NYU505.txt unknown Seq: 35 16-OCT-07 14:37
1468 NEW YORK UNIVERSITY LAW REVIEW [Vol. 82:1434
Prosecutorial Overreaching: One also sees the potential for abuse
in the seemingly inappropriate terms that have appeared in some of
the more recent prosecution agreements.
156
These sorts of terms push
the boundaries of what should be included in criminal punishment,
but remain available due to individual prosecutors’ virtually unfet-
tered discretion. Deputy Attorney General approval could also help
remedy this problem. Centralized review of agreement terms could
ensure that bizarre and inappropriate conditions,
157
especially those
pandering to local interests, would be detected and removed.
To some extent, consultation of this sort with central DOJ prob-
ably does happen.
158
It is not, however, official policy, and the hap-
hazard nature of these agreements testifies to the lack of any
centralizing standard. Central DOJ can and should provide such a
standard. This approval process will no doubt cause some administra-
tive headaches, but the costs will be a small price to pay to ensure
consistency and fairness in corporate prosecutions.
Of course, even with such an approval system, corporations will
still be vulnerable due to their legal and social relationship to the
criminal justice system. Such reform would, however, at least allow
corporations to expect a more uniform approach to punishment. Fur-
thermore, if such a vetting system failed to direct prosecutorial discre-
tion in a principled manner, Congress or the courts would have a
clearer mandate to step in and contemplate changes to the black letter
law.
C
ONCLUSION
The black letter law of entity liability is remarkably broad,
though it has traditionally been limited by prosecutors’ discretion.
The use of prosecution agreements, however, has enabled prosecutors
to overcome many of the traditional concerns with corporate liability,
thus permitting a more aggressive application of criminal law against
corporations. While the prosecution of corporate criminality is a posi-
tive development, the unique weaknesses of corporations in the crim-
inal justice system has vested a dangerous amount of power in the
hands of individual prosecutors. The DOJ has recognized this and has
156
See supra notes 127–31 and accompanying text.
157
See supra notes 127–33 and accompanying text.
158
The former U.S. Attorney for the Southern District of New York, David Kelley,
would have prosecuted KPMG criminally if not for the intervention of Deputy Attorney
General James Comey, who insisted on a deferred prosecution agreement. Corporate
Crime Reporter, Crime Without Conviction: The Rise of Deferred and Non-Prosecution
Agreements, http://www.corporatecrimereporter.com/deferredreport.htm (last visited
August 16, 2007).
\\server05\productn\N\NYU\82-5\NYU505.txt unknown Seq: 36 16-OCT-07 14:37
November 2007] CORPORATE PROSECUTION AGREEMENTS 1469
attempted to constrain some aspects of prosecutorial discretion with
the McNulty Memo. This is a worthwhile development, but more
needs to be done. The consultation framework established in the
McNulty Memo should be expanded to include decisions relating to
prosecution agreements. Such a change will not erase the bargaining
inequities between corporations and prosecutors, but it will ensure
that the use of prosecutorial discretion is exercised in a more consis-
tent and fair manner. The current relationship between corporate
prosecutors and their target companies is ripe for abuse—the DOJ
needs to expand its supervision efforts to ensure that corporate crim-
inal sanctions are used in a principled and consistent manner.