Catastrophic Risk and Credit Markets
Mark J. Garmaise
and Tobias J. Moskowitz
ABSTRACT
We provide a model of the effects of catastrophic risk on real estate financing and prices and
demonstrate that insurance market imperfections can restrict the supply of credit for catastrophe-
susceptible properties. Using unique micro-level data, we find that earthquake risk decreased
commercial real estate loan provision by 22 percent in our California properties in the 1990’s. The
effects are more severe in African-American neighborhoods. We show that the 1994 Northridge
earthquake had only a short-term disruptive effect. Our basic findings are confirmed for hurricane
risk, and our model and empirical work have implications for terrorism and political perils.
UCLA Anderson School and Graduate School of Business, University of Chicago and NBER, respectively. We thank
Bing Han, Robert Novy-Marx and participants at the Vail Real Estate Research Conference for helpful comments.
We thank AIR Worldwide Corporation, Guy Carpenter and COMPS.com for providing data. Moskowitz thanks the
Center for Research in Security Prices and the Neubauer Family Faculty Fellowship for financial support.
Correspondence to: Mark Garmaise, UCLA Anderson School, 110 Westwood Plaza, Los Angeles, CA 90095-1484.
Catastrophic events can dramatically affect the well-being of people throughout entire regions.
Episodes such as September 11, 2001, the December 26, 2004 tsunami in Asia, and Hurricane
Katrina in August 2005 highlight the risks borne by individuals, particularly those with limited
financial resources. Financial markets can help to manage these risks by playing two crucial roles.
First, markets provide a mechanism through which risk is allocated efficiently. Second, financial
markets can serve as a stable source of funding during post-catastrophe periods. Little is known,
however, about how well financial markets perform these functions. In this paper, we provide
a model of the effects of catastrophe risk on the financing and pricing of properties and find
corroborating evidence for the model using unique micro-level data on earthquake risk (the average
annual loss due to earthquake damage) and credit. We show that apparent inefficiencies in the
supply of catastrophe insurance have a substantial ongoing distortionary effect on credit markets.
In particular, our results indicate that earthquake risk reduced the provision of bank financing
by approximately 22 percent in California commercial real estate loan markets in the 1990’s. We
also find, however, that the large 1994 Northridge earthquake affected the market for only about
three months following the event. This suggests that while catastrophic risk may not be generally
allocated efficiently, the additional distortions caused by even significant catastrophic events are
quite short-lived. Our work highlights general features of catastrophic risk markets that are shared
by a variety of perils including hurricane, terrorism and political risks. We extend our basic findings
to hurricane risk and argue that our results imply that, in the absence of well-functioning insurance
markets, terrorism risk is likely to discourage bank financing of properties in high profile U.S. cities
and political risk may impede the development of corporate debt markets in emerging economies.
Our model examines the potential distortionary effect of catastrophe risk on credit markets.
1
We emphasize that bank financing of catastrophe-susceptible properties is likely to be inefficient
for two reasons. First, banks are not expert in assessing or repairing catastrophic damage to prop-
erties. As a result, banks are likely to inefficiently liquidate properties affected by a catastrophe.
Second, banks do not specialize in monitoring whether owners are implementing all positive NPV
safety-enhancing investments. In the presence of a bank loan, owners may prefer not to make
these investments. Insurers, by contrast, are expert in b oth assessing catastrophic damages and in
monitoring the execution of safety-increasing improvements, so the presence of a well-functioning
1
The management of catastrophic risk has been the theme of a recent stream of research analyzing insurance
(Jaffee and Russell, 1997, Niehaus, 2002, Zanjani, 2002), reinsurance (Froot and O’Connell, 1997, Froot, 2001) and
catastrophic-loss derivatives (Cummins, Lalonde and Phillips, 2004).
1
insurance market can ameliorate the problems in bank financing of properties at risk of a catastro-
phe. Froot (2001), however, contends that catastrophe insurance is over-priced and in relatively
short supply due to capital market imperfections and market power enjoyed by the relatively small
number of catastrophe reinsurers. We show that a p oorly functioning catastrophe insurance market
will lead to less bank financing of catastrophe-susceptible properties, reduced market participation
by less-wealthy investors and incomplete insurance coverage. Inefficiencies in the catastrophe in-
surance market will also derail positive NPV investments by investors who require loans.
To test this theory, we perform an empirical analysis using unique data on catastrophic earth-
quake risk and commercial property loan contracts and prices in the U.S. in the 1990s. Using data
from Standard and Poor’s (S&P) ratings of commercial mortgage-backed securities (CMBS), we
show that only 35% of properties in earthquake zones carry earthquake insurance and the prob-
ability that insurance is purchased is increasing in earthquake risk. These findings are consistent
with our model and suggest that earthquake insurance is inefficiently supplied.
To analyze the impact of earthquake risk on the provision of finance, we match property-level
financing and price information on commercial properties from COMPS.com with a unique data
set of micro-level earthquake risks, provided by AIR Worldwide Corporation (AIR). We find that
increased earthquake risk dramatically reduces the likelihood that a property will be financed
with bank debt, controlling for census tract fixed effects. This within-neighborhood identification
is empirically feasible b ecause differences in soil conditions create highly localized variation in
the effects of earthquakes; the AIR earthquake risks reflect both fault location and detailed soil
condition data. Our results suggest that in Los Angeles county, for example, the median quake
risk reduces the probability of bank financing by over 20 percent. This evidence indicates that
imperfections in the allo cation of catastrophe risk disrupt credit markets in a manner consistent
with the theory.
We then examine the cross-section of properties to determine if these effects are stronger for
different groups of buyers or properties in ways predicted by the theory. We show that when insur-
ance firms (insurers or insurance brokers) purchase properties, earthquake risk has a significantly
smaller affect on the probability that a bank loan is used to finance the property than it does for
other buyers. This is consistent with the idea that insurance firms have better access to earthquake
insurance and are therefore not as severely affected by the general lack of supply. As predicted
by the model, the use of bank credit by insurance firms is thus less distorted by the presence of
2
earthquake risk.
We also find that older properties and properties in areas with large African-American popula-
tions are especially unlikely to be financed with bank debt in the presence of quake risk, controlling
for the overall provision of bank loans. Earthquakes are likely to cause greater damage to older
properties, so quake risk is probably most important for these buildings. Earthquake insurance
may be particularly hard to obtain in African-American neighborhoods, which would create more
serious credit distortions linked to earthquake risk in these areas. Although it is not directly re-
lated to our theory, we further show that quake risk has an unusually strong negative effect on the
provision of bank credit in areas slated for development.
Earthquake risk also influences the characteristics of buyers and financing banks. We find that
in the pool of non-corporate buyers, the purchasers of high quake risk properties come from zip
codes with higher median home values. This supports the implication of the model that properties
with higher catastrophic risks will be purchased by buyers who are wealthier on average. We
also show that local banks are relatively more likely to finance high quake risk properties, which
is consistent with the idea underlying the theory that damage assessment and monitoring (both
better performed by nearby, rather than distant, banks) are more important for properties with
greater catastrophe risk.
In addition to its disruptive influence on real estate financing, our model shows that catastrophic
risk has a direct effect on asset pricing: properties at risk for earthquake damage should have lower
prices, reflecting their increased potential for physical destruction. We find, however, that there is
substantial variability in the manner in which quake risk is priced. In particular, we show that it is
only in larger deals that buyers consistently apply greater discounts to properties with higher quake
risk than others in the same census tract. Small buyers may not have access to highly localized
quake risk data due to either a lack of information or because acquisition of such information
involves paying some fixed cost and they are of insufficient scale.
We also examine the aftermath of one of the largest earthquakes in recent history, the January,
1994, Northridge earthquake, which caused an estimated $42 billion in damages ($14 billion of
which was insured). The Northridge quake caused a negative shock to the supply of earthquake
insurance, and we study the impact and longevity of this shock. Our analysis shows that, consistent
with the theory, properties with high quake risk were especially unlikely to be financed with bank
loans in the period directly following the Northridge quake. The insurance supply shock generated
3
by the quake further exacerbated the reduced provision of bank loans to high catastrophe risk
properties. The duration of this effect was approximately 3 months. We demonstrate that local
banks were less likely to make loans to high-quake-risk properties in the period after the event. We
also find that, as the model predicts, bank-financed transactions were concentrated in lower-risk
properties following the Northridge quake, while cash-financed transaction displayed no such shift.
All these effects were short-term and the earthquake appears to have had no significant medium-
or long-term impact on the pricing and financing of catastrophe risk.
Our model emphasizes general features of catastrophic risk markets: inefficiencies in bank
liquidation of catastrophically-damaged properties, lack of bank specialization in monitoring safety-
improving investments and restricted supply of catastrophe insurance. These features are shared
by an assortment of catastrophic perils including earthquake, hurricane, terrorism and political
risks. Earthquake data is particularly suitable for testing the theory for two reasons. First, risk
assessors can generate objective quantitative measures of earthquake risk. Second, earthquake risk
varies at the highly local level, which enables the use of census tract fixed effects to control for
unobservables. Our empirical results using the earthquake data show the relevance of the theory
and therefore support the application of the model’s predictions to other catastrophic risk markets.
To explore the broader implications of our findings, we extend the empirical work to an analysis
of hurricane risk, which shares many of the features of earthquake peril. While the properties in
our sample have relatively low exposure to hurricanes, we do find evidence that properties with
higher hurricane risk than others in the same zip code tend to receive less bank financing. This
effect is magnified when the price of catastrophe insurance is high. These results provide further
evidence for the theory in a second catastrophic risk setting.
Terrorism risk has recently become a subject of intense interest. We argue that the supply of
terrorism risk insurance is likely to be even more restricted than that of natural disaster insur-
ance for three reasons. First, terrorism risk is particularly difficult to evaluate and this ambiguity
can hamper the supply of insurance (Hogarth and Kunreuther, 1985). Second, terrorism is en-
dogenous, so markets set up to allocate terrorism risk may be manipulated (Poteshman, 2006).
Third, the damages from a catastrophic act of terrorism may be may greater than those caused
by natural phenomena. As a result, the effects we document for earthquake risk are likely to be
more severe for terrorism. This suggests that a decision by the government to decline to support
the terrorism insurance market (for example, by refusing to renew the Terrorism Risk Insurance
4
Act) can have important consequences. In particular, our work suggests that in the absence of
government-subsidized terrorism insurance, high profile and high density areas such as the down-
towns of large U.S. cities would be likely to experience both a significant shift away from bank
financing of properties and market exit by less well-capitalized investors. Our findings also indicate
that reconstruction after a terrorism incident would likely be hampered by an especially limited
supply of credit in the immediate period following an event.
Political risk such as nationalization or currency controls (which are typically of greatest concern
in emerging economies) exhibits properties similar to those of other catastrophic perils: huge po-
tential losses and lack of bank skill in liquidating affected investments. Political risk, like terrorism,
also faces the problem of uncertain hazard assessment, and the supply of political risk insurance
is quite limited (Hamdani et al., 2005). Our model and empirical work thus indicate that less
well-capitalized firms that require financing will be significantly more likely to invest in emerging
markets if there is a sufficient supply of fairly priced political risk insurance. Our results linking
catastrophe insurance to loan provision also suggest that an efficient political risk insurance market
will encourage the issuance of emerging market corporate bonds.
The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section I describes our theoretical model
of the pricing and financing of catastrophe risk. Section II details the commercial real estate and
earthquake data. Section III investigates the effects of earthquake risk on real estate financing and
prices. Section IV analyzes the impact of the Northridge quake. In Section V we consider the
implications of our findings for hurricane, terrorism and political risks. Section VI concludes.
I. Model
We develop a theory of the pricing and financing of properties in the presence of catastrophic risk.
We begin with a simple model of identical investors all of whom are financially unconstrained.
We then consider the presence of an investor with a higher valuation (or private benefits), who is
potentially financially constrained. We will argue that banks are inefficient at financing catastrophe-
susceptible properties, but that this inefficiency can be ameliorated by insurers. We conclude the
model by examining the implications of imperfections in the supply of catastrophic insurance for
the financing of properties.
5
A. Unconstrained investors
For simplicity, consider a property generating cash flow C
t
each period t with an associated dis-
count rate r for these cash flows. We assume that C
t+1
= α
t+1
C
t
, where the {α
s
} are mutually
independent and E[α
s
] = 1 for all s. This implies that E[C
t+1
|C
t
] = C
t
. Properties differ in
their susceptibility to catastrophic (e.g., earthquake or hurricane) damage.
2
For each property, a
parameter p describes both the probability that the property will be affected by a catastrophe and
the severity of any such catastrophe. Each period t with probability p there is no catastrophe.
With probability 1 p a catastrophe occurs and leaves the property with a salvage value that is
a fraction R
t
of the undamaged property value V
t
, where R
t
[0, 1] is a random variable.
3
We
also assume for simplicity that the current cash flows are lost.
4
We presume that the {R
t
} are
identically and independently distributed, with common mean E[R] (0, 1). We refer to (1 p) as
the catastrophic risk of the property.
In the event of a catastrophe, we assume that instantaneous repairs costing (1 R
t
)V
t
must
be undertaken before the property will generate future cash flows.
5
The net present value of these
repairs when there is a catastrophe is N (V
t
, R
t
) = V
t
R
t
0. We assume that catastrophe risk
(both frequency and severity) is uncorrelated with economy-wide financial wealth (as argued by
Froot, 2001) and that investors are well diversified and financially unconstrained. Investors will
always undertake the repairs, since N 0.
The average annual loss q is defined as q = (1 p)(1 E[R]), which is the expected fraction
of property value that is destroyed by the catastrophe in each period. The average annual loss
is sometimes described as the catastrophe premium (R¨uttener, Liechti and Eugster, 1999). Using
standard arguments, we show in the Appendix that V
t
=
pC
t
r+q
. The cap rate (ratio of earnings to
price) is thus given by
r+q
p
.
The above straightforward discrete time model yields the basic intuitions necessary for our tests.
Duffie and Singleton (1999) provide a general theoretical treatment of the pricing of assets in the
2
The model applies to all cases of damage risk (e.g., fire), but, as we will discuss, the insurance supply distortions
that play a role in the theory are most plausible for catastrophe risk.
3
The scientific literature on earthquakes has established the Gutenberg-Richter frequency magnitude law, which
states that magnitudes are governed by an exponential distribution, with relatively little variation across locations in
the exponential parameter (Kagan, 1997). While the frequency of earthquakes can vary substantially across regions,
the distribution of earthquake severities, given an event, is actually quite stable across areas. This result suggests
that modelling the severity of the damage as independent of its frequency is reasonable. Hurricanes, cyclones and
flo ods also exhibit similar frequency-magnitude patterns (MacDonald, 2000).
4
The results hold for fractional cash flow losses as well.
5
Assuming that a catastrophe also changes the future cash flows generated by a property has no effect on the
results.
6
presence of exogenous value-destruction risk.
Our first result describes the pricing effects of catastrophe risk: properties subject to catastrophe
risk sell for lower multiples of their current cash flows.
Result 1. The derivative of the cap rate with respect to the average annual loss is at least one.
The proofs of all Results are given in the Appendix.
B. Constrained Investors and Differential Valuations
We now introduce two modifications to the base model. First, for a given property with current
value V
s
in period s, with probability ζ there is an investor who can generate an additional value
b 0 from purchasing the property and managing it for the next period. This additional valuation
might arise from a positive net present value investment known only to the investor or from a
private benefit. For simplicity we will assume that b is a private benefit, though our results are not
sensitive to that assumption. The realization of b is known to the investor.
Second, we assume that this investor has wealth w
L
< V
s
with probability l (0, 1). With
probability (1l ), the investor has wealth w
H
> V
s
. That is, we now allow for financially constrained
investors who do not have enough cash to purchase the property. The investor with a private benefit
pays only the market value V
s
if he purchases the property. This is true, for example, if the property
is sold in a public auction.
B.1. Inefficiency of Bank Financing in the Absence of Insurance
We begin by assuming that no catastrophic insurance is available. Constrained investors will require
a bank loan. Banks have unlimited capital, and we assume that the banking sector is competitive;
our focus is on credit market distortions that are related to catastrophic risk, rather than general
credit market distortions. We presume that the bank financing of catastrophe-susceptible properties
is inefficient. This inefficiency may arise from two possible sources.
First, banks do not specialize in the evaluation or remediation of catastrophic damage. We
presume that a catastrophe creates an information asymmetry between the owner, who can gauge
the damage, and the bank, which does not specialize in damage assessment. Banks lack the or-
ganizational skill to evaluate or repair catastrophic damage.
6
While asymmetric information and
liquidation (i.e., foreclosure) costs are, in practice, to some degree present for every property, these
6
Anderson and Weinrobe (1986) and Shah and Rosenbaum (1996) find that large earthquakes lead to mortgage
defaults. Ciochetti (1997) shows that the costs of foreclosure on commercial mortgages can be substantial.
7
considerations are greatly magnified for properties damaged in an earthquake.
7
Second, banks do not specialize in monitoring whether a property owner is implementing all pos-
itive net present value (NPV) damage-reducing safety investments. In the presence of bank debt, an
owner may prefer to forgo these investments, since he b ears the costs and the bank enjoys a portion
of the benefits (Smith and Warner, 1979). The bank financing of catastrophe-susceptible properties
will thus lead to inefficient underinvestment in positive NPV safety enhancement projects.
Consider a property with value V
s
that may experience a catastrophe with probability (1 p).
Both of the two arguments just given suggest that if an investor purchases the property with w in
equity and a bank loan of V
s
w 0, then the inefficiency associated with bank financing will result
in value destruction, which we denote by loss(w, V
s
, p). We will assume that the value destruction
satisfies two properties:
Property 1: loss(w, V
s
, p) is decreasing in p and w
Property 2: loss(w, V
s
, p) > 0 if V
s
> w and p < 1, but loss(w, V
s
, p) = 0 if V
s
= w or if p = 1
The first property captures the idea that the expected efficiency losses generated by either costly
bank liquidation of damaged properties or by poor bank monitoring of damage prevention projects
are more severe both when the catastrophe risk is high and when the equity provided by the investor
is low. The second property specifies that if there is no catastrophe risk, or if the project is wholly
equity financed, then there is no value destruction. The presence of some catastrophe risk combined
with bank financing always leads to a measure of inefficiency, however small.
In the appendix we provide a formal model of the first argument analyzing the effects of a
bank’s inability to assess or repair catastrophic damage. We show that this formal model yields
the two properties detailed above. The intuition underlying the second argument suggests that
the importance of damage prevention projects will increase in the catastrophe risk. Investors who
invest more equity will capture more of the benefits of the projects, and are thus more likely to
pursue them. The second argument thus quite naturally also gives rise to the two properties.
We define Π
B
(w, V
s
, p) to be the net present value received by this investor if he invests w V
s
in cash and borrows V
s
w in order to purchase a property with catastrophe frequency (1 p).
7
Thomas (1997), for example, describes a set of apartment buildings moderately or severely damaged in the
Northridge quake that were seized by a bank after mortgage default. Three and a half years after the quake, fewer
than half the buildings were habitable. Repair of non-defaulted properties was essentially complete by that time.
Damage assessment is difficult even for insurers. Estimates by insurers of their losses in the January 1994 Northridge
earthquake grew from $5.5 billion in June 1994 to $12.5 billion in July 1995 (Roth, 1998).
8
The value of the investor’s equity claim is equal to the value V
s
of the property minus the value
of the bank’s debt claim minus any value destroyed in inefficient liquidation. Credit markets are
competitive, so the net present value of the investor’s investment is therefore equal to his private
benefit minus the value destroyed in inefficient liquidation. Since not investing is always an option,
we have
Π
B
(w, V
s
, p) = max{b loss(w, V
s
, p), 0}.
B.2. Insurance Market
We now introduce the possibility of catastrophe insurance. We will assume that there are two
potential insurers and that they offer full insurance contracts (covering all cash flow and property
value losses), though our results are not sensitive to either of these assumptions. Insurers differ
from banks in two respects. First, insurers are assumed to have the ability to swiftly evaluate the
extent of catastrophic damage for claims payment purposes. Second, insurers can monitor owners
and ensure that they make damage-preventing positive NPV investments. We presume that loan
contracts can be written that have a first priority claim on insurance payouts. The provision
of insurance thus removes the two sources of inefficiency associated with the bank financing of
properties subject to catastrophe risk. The insurer’s claim payment in the event of a catastrophe
reveals the extent of the damage to the bank and removes the information asymmetry between the
property owner and the bank. The insurer will also undertake the monitoring of safety projects.
We presume, however, that the catastrophe insurance market is potentially imperfectly com-
petitive. In particular, due to market power or capital constraints on the part of reinsurers (Froot,
2001), we assume that each insurer is able to make a bid on any given catastrophe insurance con-
tract with probability n [0, 1]. Whether an insurer can bid is independent of what happens to his
competitor. Each insurer who can bid proposes a price for full insurance, and the property owner
may select the lower bid or choose not to purchase insurance. We describe the insurance market as
perfectly competitive if n = 1 and imperfectly competitive otherwise. The fair value of insurance
is the market value of the insurance payout.
8
We describe the bid of an insurer by viewing it as a surplus, sur, over the fair value of the
insurance. If both insurers bid for the contract, the unique equilibrium is for each to set sur = 0. If
only one insurer bids, he will choose sur to maximize his exp ected profits. Financially unconstrained
8
For simplicity, we ignore the costs associated with damage assessment and monitoring. Including these costs does
not affect the results.
9
investors will never pay a positive premium for insurance, since they need not finance with a loan
and will therefore never suffer the inefficiencies of bank financing, so the insurer maximizes the
profits he realizes from selling to constrained investors. Any bid sur > w
L
will be rejected, since
the investor will have insufficient resources to pay this amount. The bid will also be rejected if it is
less expensive for the investor to purchase the property without insurance: sur > l oss(w
L
, V
s
, p).
Lastly, if sur > b, the investor will prefer to forego the property purchase rather than buying
insurance.
Insurers do not know the realization of the private benefit b, but they know its associated cdf
F
b
and pdf f
b
. We assume that F
b
satisfies the MHR property. We denote by b
the solution to the
following maximization problem:
max
y0
·
y (1 F
b
(y)) +
Z
y
0
f
b
(t)tdt
¸
. (1)
The MHR property guarantees that b
is unique. An insurer bidding alone will set sur =
min{b
, w
L
, loss(w
L
, V
s
, p)}. As a property’s catastrophic risk increases, Property 1 indicates that
the option of financing with a bank loan becomes increasingly unattractive. This implies that as
catastrophe risk increases two things occur in an imperfectly competitive insurance market: A
single insurer bidding will charge a higher surplus and if no insurer bids the investor is less likely to
proceed with the purchase. Both of these effects reduce the frequency of bank-financed transactions.
If the insurance market is perfectly competitive, insurance is always supplied at zero surplus.
Result 2. If the insurance market is imperfectly competitive, the probability that a transaction
is financed with bank debt is decreasing in the property’s catastrophic risk. If the insurance market
is perfectly competitive, the probability that a transaction is financed with bank debt is independent
of the property’s catastrophic risk.
In an imperfectly competitive insurance market, expensive insurance premiums combined with
the inefficiency of bank financing in the absence of insurance together discourage less wealthy
investors from purchasing properties with high catastrophic risk. Even though the credit mar-
ket itself is competitive, the insufficient supply of insurance leads to distortions in the financing
of catastrophe-susceptible properties. Investors with substantial wealth purchase the properties
without insurance or a loan.
Result 3. If the insurance market is imperfectly competitive, the average wealth of the pur-
chasing investor is increasing in the property’s catastrophic risk. If the insurance market is per-
10
fectly competitive, the average wealth of the purchasing investor is independent of the property’s
catastrophic risk.
As catastrophic risk increases, Property 1 shows that fewer financially constrained investors
will buy the property without insurance. In an imperfect insurance market, if insurance is offered,
the surplus demanded will increase with catastrophic risk, but in such a way that the investor will
still prefer to buy insurance rather than purchasing the property without it. The net effect is that
as catastrophic risk increases, more of the bank-financed transactions will carry insurance. In a
perfect insurance market, insurance will always b e purchased because it avoids the inefficiencies of
bank financing.
Result 4. If the insurance market is imperfectly competitive, the probability that a bank-financed
transaction is accompanied with insurance is increasing in the property’s catastrophic risk. If the
insurance market is perfectly competitive, all bank-financed purchases of properties with positive
catastrophic risk will be accompanied with insurance.
As catastrophic risk increases, in an imperfect insurance market, two classes of investors elect
not to purchase the property. First, constrained investors who receive no insurance bid and find the
cost of financing the property without insurance too high. Second, constrained investors who receive
one bid and find both the insurance bid and the cost of financing the property without insurance
too high. Since it is economically efficient for the investor to always purchase the property, this
suggests that there are social welfare costs arising from imperfections in the insurance market:
positive net present value projects must be abandoned.
Result 5. If the insurance market is imperfectly competitive, the probability of a transaction is
decreasing in the property’s catastrophic risk. If the insurance market is perfectly competitive, the
probability of a transaction is independent of the property’s catastrophic risk.
We also consider the effects of a change in the competitiveness of the insurance market, such
as might arise following a large catastrophic event. As competitiveness increases, more financially
constrained investors will be able to purchase affordable insurance and buy properties.
Result 6. The probability that a transaction is financed with debt is increasing in insurance
market competitiveness n.
An increase in competitiveness will particularly benefit constrained investors considering pur-
chasing high-catastrophe-risk properties. Thus, as competitiveness increases, there should be an
especially large increase in bank-financed purchases of high-risk properties. Unconstrained in-
11
vestors using cash to make their property purchases will be unaffected by the competitiveness of
the insurance market.
Result 7. The average catastrophic risk of bank-financed transactions is increasing in insurance
market competitiveness n. The average catastrophic risk of all-cash transactions is independent of
insurance market competitiveness n.
In Section III we will test these predictions using empirical data on earthquakes. Clearly, in
practice, the insurance market will not be perfectly competitive. Our empirical results, however,
will examine the importance of this imperfection and quantify its spillover effects on credit markets.
II. Data and Summary Statistics
We briefly describe the variety of data sources used in the paper.
A. Transaction-level data from the U.S. commercial real estate market
Our transaction-level commercial real estate sample consists of 32,618 transactions drawn from
across the U.S. over the period January 1, 1992 to March 30, 1999 compiled by COMPS.com, a
leading provider of commercial real estate sales data. Garmaise and Moskowitz (2003, 2004) provide
an extensive description of the COMPS database and detailed summary statistics. The data span
11 states: California, Nevada, Oregon, Massachusetts, Maryland, Virginia, Texas, Georgia, New
York, Illinois, and Colorado, plus the District of Columbia.
Commercial properties are grouped into ten mutually exclusive types: retail, industrial, apart-
ment, office, hotel, commercial land, residential land, industrial land, mobile home park and special.
Panel A of Table I reports summary statistics on the properties in our sample. The average (me-
dian) sale price is $2.2 million ($590,000), and there are only 42 transactions involving REITS (less
than 0.2% of the sample). Capitalization rates, defined as current net income on the property
divided by sale price, and property age are also reported.
The COMPS database provides detailed information about specific property transactions, in-
cluding property location, identity and location of market participants, and financial structure.
In particular, COMPS provides eight digit latitude and longitude coordinates of the property’s
location (accurate to within 10 meters).
The COMPS data contain financing information for each property transaction. We focus on the
terms of the loan contract, including interest rates, and the size and presence of loans. As Panel A
12
of Table I indicates, the average loan size (from bank and non-bank institutions) as a fraction of
sale price is over 75%. Bank loans are used in 53% of transactions, vendor-to-buyer (VTB) loans
(i.e., seller financing) are used in 19% of deals and less than 5% of deals involve assumed debt. The
data also contain rich detail on loan terms including the annual interest rate, the maturity of the
loan, whether the loan rate is floating or fixed, whether amortized and the length of amortization,
and whether the loan is subsidized by the Small Business Administration (only 1.3% of loans). The
COMPS data do not, however, include insurance information on properties.
B. Commercial Mortgage-Backed Securities Data
We make use of data on CMBS transactions provided by the S&P RatingsDirect database. This
data provides descriptive details on fifty CMBS transactions over the period 1996 to 1999. Each
CMBS issuance covers multiple properties, as described in Panel B of Table I, and in many cases
information on earthquake risk and insurance is given.
C. Earthquake risk
AIR Worldwide Corporation (AIR) provides detailed data on the earthquake risks associated with
our COMPS properties’ locations. AIR is a highly regarded vendor of estimates for various types
of catastrophe risks. Using its proprietary CATStation Hazard Module, AIR generates location-
specific assessments of the expected average annual loss due to earthquake risk. (Cummins, Lalonde
and Phillips, 2004 describe the AIR catastrophe models.) The average annual loss denotes the
fraction of property value that is expected to be destroyed by an earthquake in any given year. It is
expressed as a percentage, and it reflects both the likelihood of an earthquake and the distribution
over potential severities. Prop erty characteristics will also have an effect on the impact of an
earthquake, but the AIR estimates incorporate only location, not structure, characteristics.
9
We
use AIR’s estimate of average annual loss as our measure of quake risk. AIR provides location-
specific matches for each of our COMPS properties at eight digit latitude and longitude coordinates,
which are accurate to within 10 meters.
The AIR earthquake model uses both fault location and detailed soil condition data. Soil
characteristics have a large impact on the way seismic waves are transmitted. Using this data,
the AIR model makes highly localized predictions of average annual loss. For example, the AIR
soil database for the area around the San Francisco Bay has a horizontal resolution of 24 square
9
AIR does generate structure-specific estimates, but these were not provided to us.
13
meters.
10
Panel B of Table I presents summary statistics for AIR earthquake risks. For most properties
in our sample, the average annual loss is described as less than 0.1%, which we code as 0. There
are 9,785 properties with positive quake risks, all located in California, Oregon and a handful of
sites in Massachusetts. Our data include 12,288 properties in California and 9,386 properties in
Los Angeles county.
In many cases the S&P data supplies earthquake risk and insurance data on the properties
securing the CMBS issuance. For properties in earthquake zones (primarily California, but also
including parts of Nevada, Washington, Oregon, Utah and Missouri) the probable maximum loss
(PML) is often specified, along with information about whether the property has earthquake in-
surance. S&P defines the PML to be the expected earthquake damage (expressed as a fraction of
property replacement cost) that has a ten percent chance of being exceeded during a fifty year pe-
riod (Standard and Poor’s, 2003). This measure of earthquake risk is closely related to the average
annual loss. In most cases, the S&P data will specify only whether the PML exceeds a threshold,
typically 20%.
D. The Northridge Earthquake
Our data and sample time period also allow us to consider the impact of an actual sizable earth-
quake, the Northridge earthquake of January 17, 1994. The Northridge earthquake measured 6.7
on the Richter scale, caused 57 deaths and was responsible for direct economic damages of approx-
imately $42 billion (of which $14 billion was insured), according to reliable estimates (Petak and
Elahi, 2000). The U.S. Geological Survey (USGS) provides data on the severity of ground mo-
tion during the Northridge quake.
11
Specifically, we consider the peak ground acceleration (PGA),
which is the maximum acceleration experienced at a specified location on the earth’s surface during
the course of an earthquake. The PGA is a commonly used metric for earthquake severity, and
building codes often describe requirements for withstanding shaking in terms of horizontal force,
which is related to PGA. Data is provided for points on a grid system, with a distance between
grid p oints of approximately 1.15 miles on the north-south axis and 0.94 miles on the east-west
axis. We match our property locations to the nearest grid point in order to infer the extent of local
10
This description of the AIR model is drawn from http://www.air-worldwide.com. The January 1994 Northridge
earthquake caused some revisions to earthquake risk assessments. All the results in the paper are robust to using
only post-January 1994 data.
11
The data may b e found at http://earthquake.usgs.gov/shakemap.
14
PGA. This process generates PGA estimates for every COMPS property in Los Angeles county.
Summary statistics are given in Panel B of Table I.
E. Crime and Census Data
We also make use of local crime and census data. The crime risk data is provided by CAP Index,
Inc., who compute a crime score for a particular location by combining data from police reports,
the FBI’s
Uniform Crime Report
(UCR), client loss reports, and offender and victim surveys with
geographic, economic, and population data. The crime risk estimates are property-specific for
the COMPS data and vary within census tracts (see Garmaise and Moskowitz (2005) for further
details). The census data come from the 1990 and 2000 U.S. censuses.
III. The Effects of Earthquake Risk on Financing and Prices
Using the earthquake risk and commercial property loan data, we test the hypotheses outlined in
Section I by examining the impact of earthquake risk on financing and prices. We also provide some
general descriptive statistics on the effects of earthquake risk on commercial real estate markets.
The commercial real estate market is a useful laboratory to investigate the role of catastrophe
risks because the loans are typically secured and non-recourse, providing a set of project-specific
financings for which the collateral value is of central importance.
A. Quake risk and insurance
The theory in Section I advanced the argument that an imperfectly competitive catastrophe in-
surance market can imp ede the supply of credit in the real estate market. Catastrophe insurance
reduces the costs of securing a loan because it avoids inefficient foreclosures (liquidations) by banks
after a catastrophe. If catastrophe insurance is priced at a premium, as suggested by Froot (2001),
then buyers who require a loan will only purchase insurance when the costs of inefficient liquidation
are very high, i.e. for high-quake-risk properties. This idea is captured in Result 4, which states
that in imperfectly competitive insurance markets the probability that a bank-financed transac-
tion is accompanied with insurance is increasing in the property’s catastrophe risk. In perfectly
competitive insurance markets, all bank-financed properties should carry catastrophe insurance.
Insurance data on individual properties is quite difficult to secure (Squires, O’Connor and Silver,
2001), but the S&P CMBS database provides this information on properties in quake-susceptible
areas as part of its ratings process. The properties in this database have securitized loans, which
15
make up a significant (and growing) fraction of total commercial mortgage lending during our
sample period.
12
Hence, these properties are representative of our larger database on commercial
real estate from COMPS, which does not contain information on quake insurance. Panel C of Table
I shows that for the 482 properties in the S&P CMBS transactions that reside in quake-prone areas,
only 169 or 35% purchased earthquake insurance. Among properties facing the highest quake risk
(those with probable maximum loss, PML, > 20%), the fraction obtaining earthquake insurance is
54%. These results are consistent with Result 4 from the model of Section I.
As a more formal test, Table II presents results from regressions relating quake risk to the
purchase of quake insurance in the S&P CMBS database. There are 482 properties in earthquake
zones with catastrophe insurance information supplied by CMBS.
13
For these properties, we regress
a binary variable for whether quake insurance was purchased on an indicator variable for High quake
risk (PML above 20%). Unfortunately, the S&P CMBS database does not provide information on
quake risk other than identifying properties as high or low quake risk based on having a PML
greater than 20%. All regressions include year dummies and transaction attributes and robust
standard errors are reported throughout. In the first column of Table II, we display results from
a logit regression. The coefficient on High quake risk is statistically significant with a t-statistic of
7.41. In the second column of Table II, we describe the results of a fixed effects (conditional) logit
regression that includes CMBS issuer fixed effects. The coefficient on High quake risk is statistically
significant with a t-statistic of 2.55. The economic magnitude of this effect is quite large. The point
estimate on High quake risk implies a 33.80 percentage point increase from 35.06% to 68.86% in the
probability of earthquake insurance being provided.
14
(The estimate from the specification in the
first column is even larger.) For this sample of debt-financed earthquake-zone properties, those with
a PML of at least 20% (e.g., high quake risk) thus have a dramatically higher probability of carrying
earthquake insurance than other properties.
15
The third column of Table II uses transaction-level
rather than issuer-level fixed effects. The magnitude of the coefficient on high quake risk diminishes
somewhat, but remains significant in both statistical (t = 3.04) and economic terms.
12
Vandell (1998) shows that by the end of 1997, 15.1 percent of general commercial real estate mortgage credit was
securitized, while 25.5 percent of apartment debt was securitized.
13
These properties are primarily located in California, though some are also located in the states of Nevada,
Washington, Oregon, Utah, and Missouri (Standard and Poor’s, 2003).
14
The economic magnitude of a fixed effects logit is best considered in terms of its impact on the odds ratio.
Earthquake insurance is provided for 35.06% of the CMBS earthquake-zone properties, which gives an o dds ratio of
0.3506
10.3506
= 0 .5399. Since the estimated coefficient on High quake risk is 1.41, moving from low to high quake risk
multiplies the odds ratio by exp(1.41) = 4.10, which yields an odds ratio of 2.21, which is equivalent to an earthquake
insurance probability of 68.86%.
15
In general, insurance is especially valuable for low frequency, highly risky, events.
16
The findings in Table II are consistent with other work showing that lenders require earthquake
insurance for high risk properties (Glickman and Stein, 2005) and that commercial real estate
investors purchase earthquake insurance primarily at the request of lenders (Porter et al., 2004).
Overall, the results are consistent with the imperfect-insurance equilibrium of Result 4. Result 4
indicates that in an imperfectly competitive insurance market not all loan-financed properties will
carry insurance, and the fraction with insurance will rise with quake risk. The evidence in Table II
and the fact that only 35% of the properties in quake zones carry insurance strongly supports the
model. The fact that these loans are securitized in public markets makes clear that diversification
of catastrophe risk is not the primary role played by insurance in the financing of properties. The
purchasers of public CMBS are very well diversified and cannot credibly be argued to be over-
exposed to California earthquake risk. The model presented in Section I, however, shows that even
properties financed by well-diversified lenders will carry earthquake insurance, so that lenders (and,
indirectly, borrowers) can avoid inefficient liquidation.
B. Quake risk and commercial financing terms
Table II provides evidence of an imperfectly competitive catastrophe insurance market. According
to Result 2, in an imperfectly competitive insurance market the probability of bank financing will
decline with catastrophic risk, while in a perfect insurance market financing and catastrophic risk
will be unrelated. Therefore, as an additional test of the competitiveness of earthquake insurance
markets, we examine the relation between bank financing and earthquake risk. Table III considers
the effect of quake risk on the commercial real estate financing terms offered by banks in the
COMPS data set. To isolate the impact of quake risk, it is important to control for neighborhood
features, since the lending environment can vary across different districts of a city (Ross and Tootell
(2004), Garmaise and Moskowitz (2005)). We conduct our tests using census tract fixed effects to
difference out unobservables at the census tract level. A census tract typically covers between 2,500
and 8,000 persons or about a 4-8 square block area in most cities, and is designed to be homogeneous
with respect to population characteristics, economic status, and living conditions (source: United
States Census Bureau). Quake risk, however, is not uniform within a census tract due to highly
localized variation in soil conditions. There are 1,210 tracts in our data set that contain properties
with p ositive quake risks, and 202 tracts (with 2,235 properties) that have within-tract variation in
17
quake risk.
16
While earthquake risk is clearly highly variable across different regions of California
and the U.S., we emphasize here that our use of census tract fixed effects means that we are
only comparing properties within the same tract. Our econometric identification arises solely from
within-tract variation.
More formally, our econometric model considers the effect of earthquake risk on the provision
of loans by banks, a binary variable indicating whether a bank loan was obtained. The equation
estimated is,
P rob(bank f inancing)
i
= F (quake risk
i
, price
i
, controls
i
, property type, year, tract) + ²
i
, (2)
where controls
i
is a vector of controls containing a set of property and neighborhood attributes for
asset i, property type, year, and tract represent property type, year, and census tract fixed effects
in which the property resides, and ²
i
is an error term. The sale price is included as a regressor to
control for value in current use, thereby isolating the component of quake risk related to secondary
or collateral value, since the theory we aim to test is about liquidation value in the event of a
catastrophic risk. We estimate a logistic functional form for the binary dependent variable.
In advance of our discussion of the empirical results, it is worthwhile to consider the econometric
issues raised by our specification in equation (2). The first point is that the sale price itself may
be a function of quake risk; we might expect high quake risk properties to realize lower prices
according to Result 1. We examine the evidence testing this result in the next section. This issue
presents no special econometric problem because the logistic model can be estimated consistently
in the presence of correlations between independent variables.
The second, and more serious, issue is that some unobservable variable (such as local financial
and economic conditions or quality of borrower or property) may have a simultaneous effect on
loan provision, sale prices, and quake risk, rendering all of our variables endogenous and difficult
to interpret. (That is, this would result in a correlation between the independent variables and the
error term.) We will return to a discussion of this omitted variables problem in Section III C.1.
We are essentially estimating reduced form equations for the probability, price, quantity, and
terms of the debt supplied. Consistent with the model in Section I and as argued earlier, we believe
these effects are closer to supply-side constraints.
16
There are 334 zip codes that contain positive quake risk properties, and 131 zip codes (with 4,666 properties)
that have within-zip-code variation in quake risk. The earthquake risk results in the paper are robust to using either
zip code or census tract fixed effects.
18
B.1. Bank loan provision
In column 1 of Table III, we report results from regressing a binary variable indicating whether
or not the property purchase is financed with a bank loan on quake risk the average annual loss
from the AIR data and a set of control variables. The control variables include a set of property,
borrower, and local market characteristics which include the log of the sale price, an indicator for
whether the transaction is brokered,
17
an indicator for whether the buyer is a broker himself, an
indicator for corporate buyers, the 1990 property and personal crime risks, the age of the property,
the distances of the buyer and seller from the property, an indicator for development projects,
and fixed effects for property type, year, and census tract. The estimation method is via fixed
effects (conditional) logit. The regression shows that properties subject to greater quake risk are
significantly less likely to be financed with a bank loan. The coefficient on quake risk is 2.63 with
a t-statistic of 2.83. To evaluate the economic magnitude of this effect, consider the Los Angeles
county observed frequency of financing of 58.5% and median quake risk of 0.2%. The point estimate
on quake risk in the regression implies a 13.1 percentage point reduction in the probability of loan
provision from 58.5 to 45.4%.
18
This reduction is 22.3% of the mean financing frequency. (The
mean quake risk in Los Angeles county is 0.25%, which generates an even larger effect.) Examining
all the California properties in our data set, for which the mean quake risk is 0.19%, the conditional
logit estimate implies a 12.4 percentage point reduction in the probability of financing, which is
22.2% of the mean. The size of these effects suggests that quake risk dramatically reduces the
provision of bank finance to properties at higher risk within the same census tract (and controlling
for price and all the other attributes).
The substantial reduction in loan provision for high quake risk properties lends support to Result
2 from our model: in a well-functioning insurance market there should be no relation between
earthquake risk and loan provision. If catastrophe risk is not efficiently supplied, then credit
markets may be distorted. This evidence corroborates Fro ot’s (2001) contention that catastrophe,
in particular earthquake, risk is not optimally allocated across market participants and may not be
correctly priced. Moreover, the magnitude of the effect we document suggests insurance markets
can have substantial distortionary effects on credit markets. A 22% reduction in the frequency
17
Garmaise and Moskowitz (2003) show that brokers have a significant effect on the financing of commercial
prop erties through their relationships with banks. We therefore add broker presence as an additional control.
18
The economic magnitude is calculated using the odds ratio, as described earlier. If, instead of a conditional logit
mo del, we run a fixed effect linear probability model (OLS), the estimated effect of a 0.2% increase in quake risk is
9.2 percentage points, with a t-statistic of 2.51 (not reported in the tables).
19
of bank financing can have significant effects on the real economy, as the finance and growth
literature emphasizes ((Peek and Rosengren (2000), Cetorelli and Gambera (2001), Klein, Peek,
and Rosengren (2002), Burgess and Pande (2003) and Garmaise and Moskowitz (2005)).
19
As
emphasized in the model in Section I (Result 5), financially constrained investors are forced to
forego positive NPV projects when they cannot purchase fairly priced insurance.
B.2. Bank loan terms and Seller financing
In columns 2 and 3 of Table III we analyze the effect of quake risk on the terms of the bank loan
contract. Our theory does not provide clear predictions about these terms but we provide some
empirical evidence to offer additional descriptive information. We first consider interest rates. In
our theory, some constrained investors purchasing quake-susceptible properties obtain a mortgage
and acquire quake insurance. For these loans, there is no quake risk faced by the borrower and
the loans are secured by both the property and the quake insurance. For a given ratio of loan
amount to property value, these loans are actually safer than loans to properties with no quake
risk (because of the value of the insurance) and may therefore carry lower interest rates. Other
constrained buyers purchasing properties subject to quake risk obtain a mortgage without quake
insurance. These loans will be riskier than loans secured by properties without quake risk and will
therefore carry higher rates. The overall effect is ambiguous.
Column 2 reports regression results of the interest rate of the loan on quake risk. In addition
to the previous controls, the ratio of loan size to property price (loan-to-value), the debt maturity,
an indicator for floating rate loans, an indicator for Small Business Administration-backed (SBA)
loans, and the log of bank assets are included as regressors. We find that quake risk has no
statistically or economically significant effect on the interest rate. A 0.2% increase in quake risk is
associated with a 17 basis point increase in the annualized interest rate (the average annual rate
in the sample is 8.3%) and is statistically no different from zero. The magnitude of this effect
contrasts sharply with the findings on loan provision and the data do not permit clear statistical
inference.
We next consider leverage ratios. The relationship between leverage ratios and quake risk is also
19
The overall rate of bank loan provision in California is 55.95%, which is actually slightly above the average rate
in the whole sample. There are, however, macroeconomic, legal and regulatory reasons for why loan provision rates
may differ across states (and indeed, the fraction of properties financed with bank loans varies quite dramatically
across states in our data). Our census-tract fixed effects control for all such factors and allow us to isolate the effects
of quake risk alone. The implication of our findings is that in the absence of quake risk, loan provision rates in
California would be roughly 12.4 percentage points higher than what we observe in the data.
20
ambiguous in the model because any feasible loan amount is optimal when insurance is acquired.
Nonetheless, to fully describe the effect of catastrophe risk on financing terms, we regress loan
size on quake risk. As is shown in column 3 of Table III, conditional on a loan being extended,
the size of the loan does not depend on quake risk. In column 4 of Table III we report results
from regressing a binary variable for the presence of seller financing on quake risk and the usual
controls. In this regression as well, we find an insignificant effect from quake risk. In unreported
results, we also find that other attributes of the loan, such as maturity, floating/fixed rate status
and the presence of multiple lenders are also not affected by quake risk. The central feature of the
relationship between quake risk and financing is the one highlighted in column 1: high quake risk
properties are significantly less likely to be financed with bank debt. This is consistent with the
implication of Result 2 when insurance markets are not fully competitive.
C. Cross-sectional Effects of Quake risk on financing terms
We further examine the role of quake risk on financing across various property attributes as a
further test of our model and to help rule out alternative explanations. We first consider the
purchase of properties by insurance firms (either insurers or insurance brokers). There are 102
insurance firms in our full sample. These insurance firms are likely to have strong relationships with
catastrophe insurance providers (perhaps within their own company) that should facilitate their
access to insurance. In essence, more catastrophe insurers are likely to bid on a property purchased
by an insurance firm, so the insurance market faced by insurance firms will be more competitive.
Result 2 thus indicates that catastrophe risk will have a smaller effect on the likelihood that an
insurance firm purchases a property with a bank loan, relative to other buyers.
In the first column of Table IV, we describe the results from regressing an indicator for the
provision of a bank loan on quake risk, quake risk interacted with an indicator for an insurance
firm buyer, an indicator for an insurance firm buyer and the usual controls. The coefficient on
the interaction between quake risk and insurance firm buyer is positive and significant, showing
that quake risk has a smaller effect on the financing of properties by insurers. Considering both
the coefficient on quake risk and its interaction with the insurance firm buyer indicator, we find
that quake risk has an insignificant effect on the probability that an insurance firm will finance a
property with a bank loan, in contrast to its strong negative effect for other buyers. This is further
evidence in favor of Result 2.
The effect of the reduction in bank loan provision induced by earthquake risk is not uniform
21
across properties. Due to innovations in technology, improved building co des and structural deterio-
ration, older properties are likely more susceptible to earthquake damage than younger, seismically-
modernized properties (Schulze et al., 1987 and Otani, 2000).
20
In the second column of Table IV, we report results from regressing an indicator for the provision
of a bank loan on quake risk, quake risk interacted with property age, property age and the usual
controls. The coefficient on the interaction between quake risk and age is highly significant and
negative, showing that quake risk has a stronger effect on the financing of older properties.
In the third column of Table IV, we examine the interaction of quake risk with the percentage
of African-Americans in the property’s census tract on loan provision. We find a negative and
significant coefficient on the interaction term: quake risk reduces the provision of bank loans es-
pecially in neighborhoods with more African-Americans. The regression includes the interaction
between quake risk and the log of median home value in the property’s census tract as a control.
This finding is consistent with the idea that property insurance is particularly difficult to acquire
in African-American neighborhoo ds, even controlling for local home values (Squires, 2003). The
census tract fixed effects control for any reduction in the general availability of bank credit in
African-American neighborho ods, so this result suggests that distortions in the insurance market
affect the supply of bank loans in these areas. An imperfect supply of catastrophe insurance thus
serves to especially harm areas with greater minority populations.
The fourth column of Table IV reports results from interacting quake risk with a development
indicator variable. We find a negative and significant coefficient on the interaction, indicating that
the financing of development deals is especially hampered by quake risk. While this finding is not
directly related to our model, it suggests that the financing of potentially high NPV development
transactions is discouraged by the presence of quake risk. Overall, the results in Table IV indicate
that quake risk makes it especially difficult to redevelop older buildings in areas with large minority
representation. This evidence suggests that neighborhood revitalization may be hindered by the
improper allocation of quake risk.
20
It may be argued that for older buildings, the land value is a larger proportion of total property value and land
is presumably less subject to earthquake risk. That may suggest that quake risk is less important for properties with
older buildings. We find, however, that land is only infrequently used to secure a bank loan (only 26% of vacant land
is financed with a bank mortgage compared to 58% of improved properties). This indicates that it is the structure
that is the primary collateral for bank loans and older structures present greater earthquake damage risks.
22
C.1. Omitted Variables
We now turn to the hypothesis that some unobserved variable is jointly determining quake risk
and loan provision. Earthquake risk itself is based on soil conditions and relative proximity to
fault lines (which are arguably exogenous), so the endogeneity concern here is one of matching
of types of properties to types of buyers or markets. Are local markets where quake risk is high
more financially constrained? Are the types of owners of high quake risk properties different
along other unobservable dimensions that might also affect the probability of bank financing?
Such unobservable effects may create an omitted variable bias that could erroneously highlight a
significant role for quake risk in predicting bank loan provision when no such role exists, or could
generate what appears to be no role for quake risk when in fact such risks are taken into account
by lenders. The sign of the potential bias is ambiguous.
To address the issue of omitted variable bias, we consider the following. First, we employ census
tract fixed effects to difference out unobservables at a level much finer than the level at which local
financial markets operate. In addition, since a census tract is designed to be homogeneous with
respect to population characteristics, economic status, and living conditions (source: United States
Census Bureau), the use of tract fixed effects helps to difference out other unobservables about the
local population. Local debt market conditions are clearly highly uniform within a census tract
(Kwast, Starr-McCluer, and Wolken, 1997), so the financing environment is unlikely to be driving
the micro-level variation we study.
21
Second, the loans we consider are non-recourse, meaning that the lender may only seek the
collateral value and not any other assets of the borrower in the event of default. The non-recourse
feature of this market implies that borrower quality should be of far less importance than collateral
value.
Third, the bank loan term results also help address omitted variable concerns. For example,
if different types of borrowers select properties (within a given census tract) with different risk
characteristics (e.g., higher quality borrowers may avoid high quake risk properties), then we should
expect quake risk to not only affect loan provision, but loan terms as well. Any unobservable quality
differences of borrowers or properties that might be related to quake risk and loan provision, would
almost certainly also be related to the financing terms the bank is willing to supply. Omitted
variable problems of this type would predict greater loan provision and better loan terms. We find,
21
The standard definition of the local banking market in the literature (e.g., Berger, Demsetz, and Strahan, 1999)
is the local Metropolitan Statistical Area (MSA) or non-MSA county.
23
however, that quake risk is only related to the probability of obtaining a loan, and is unrelated to
any loan term, so unobservable quality differences are unlikely to explain our findings.
Fourth, the lack of a significant relation between quake risk and seller financing also weighs
against an omitted variable explanation relating to unobserved borrower or property quality, which
would presumably be relevant to any lender (bank or seller). A direct role for quake risk is the only
plausible explanation for these differential effects across lender types.
Last, we also control for the current sale price of the property in an attempt to isolate the
component of quake risk related to liquidation value. Variables related to market value and quake
risk simultaneously should be captured by the sale price and, in fact, may understate the effect of
quake risk on loan provision. Potential omitted variables affecting quake risk and financing on a
specific property within a census tract, property type, and year and controlling for sale price and
other attributes, are difficult to envision.
D. Earthquake risk and Selection of Buyers and Banks
In the model, we argued that the high cost of catastrophe insurance may prevent low wealth
investors from obtaining bank loans and thus may deter them from purchasing high catastrophe
risk insurance. This is formalized in Result 3, which states that in an imp erfectly competitive
catastrophe insurance market, the average wealth of the purchasing investor is increasing in the
catastrophe risk of the property. The COMPS data do not provide the wealth of property buyers,
but they do list the zip code of the purchaser. (The census tract of the buyer is not given.) For
non-corporate (i.e., individual) buyers, the median home value in the buyer’s zip code (from the
2000 census zip code tabulation area data) is a reasonable proxy for the buyer’s wealth. In column
1 of Table V, we display the results from regressing the median home value in the buyer’s zip code
on quake risk and the usual controls, in the subsample for which the buyers are non-corporate. We
find a positive and significant coefficient on quake risk: within a given census tract, the buyers of
higher quake risk properties tend to come from wealthier zip codes. This is evidence in favor of
Result 3.
In column 2 of Table V we regress the fraction of the issuing bank’s deposits that are held within
the same county as the property on quake risk. We only include observations that include a loan
and for which we can identify the lending bank in this regression. We find a marginally significant
positive coefficient on quake risk; local banks are more likely to make loans in high quake risk areas.
It is reasonable to suggest that liquidating a building damaged in an earthquake or monitoring
24
the implementation of safety-enhancing investment may more feasibly be done by a local bank.
While this finding does not indicate, as the model presumes, that banks are, in general, inefficient
at lending to catastrophe-susceptible properties, it supports the idea that damage assessment and
monitoring (both better performed by closer banks) are important in the financing of properties
subject to catastrophic risk, as the theory assumes.
The finding in column 2 also suggests that the need for diversification is unlikely to serve as
an explanation for the importance of quake risk to financing, for otherwise the risk would best be
borne by distant banks. As further evidence on this question, in column 3 of Table V we display
results from regressing the log of the assets of the bank making a loan on quake risk, the size of the
loan, and the previous set of controls. As the table indicates, banks making loans in high quake
risk areas are not significantly larger in terms of asset size. Larger banks could presumably more
easily diversify their exposure to catastrophe risk. These results therefore do not provide support
to a risk diversification explanation.
E. Quake risk and commercial real estate pricing
Result 1 states that property cap rates should increase with quake risk, on at least a one-to-one
basis. We test this hypothesis by regressing cap rates on quake risk and the full set of controls
from Table III. We report the results from this regression in column 1 of Table VI. The results
are inconclusive: the estimated coefficient of 1.26 is consistent with Result 1, but the t-statistic of
0.85 indicates that the null hypothesis of a coefficient of zero cannot be rejected. This test appears
to have too little power to provide evidence either in favor of or opposed to Result 1. Evidence in
other studies supports Result 1: Nakagawa, Saito and Yamaga (2004, 2005) find that earthquake
risk reduces rents and land prices in Tokyo.
In a complementary test, we regress the log of sale price on quake risk, the log of earnings and
the controls. As reported in column 2 of Table VI, the coefficient on quake risk is insignificant in
this specification as well. If there is a fixed cost in evaluating the highly localized quake risk that
we are studying, it may that quake risk is only determined for larger properties. Furthermore, the
result in column 2 of Table IV indicate that quake risk is more important for older properties. In
column 3 of Table VI, we display results from regressing the log of sale price on quake risk, the
log of earnings, age, the interaction between quake risk and both the log of earnings and age and
the usual controls. We find that the interactions between quake risk and the log of earnings and
property age are both negative and significant. This suggests that quake risk has an impact on
25
property prices primarily for larger and older properties.
IV. The Impact of the Northridge Earthquake
We now turn to the impact of a specific event, the Northridge, California earthquake of January
17, 1994, on local markets.
22
In addition to the direct effects of the Northridge quake, press reports
document that earthquake insurance rates across California rose dramatically in the aftermath of
the Northridge earthquake.
23
. These indirect effects of the earthquake suggest that quake risk may
have distorted both prices and financing even in areas that experienced little physical damage.
In particular, the earthquake may have reduced the competitiveness of the catastrophe insurance
market. This shock to the supply of commercial earthquake insurance was, however, relatively
short-lived.
24
We first consider the direct and indirect effects of the earthquake on local cap rates. Earnings
are reported for the previous year, so the effect of the Northridge quake on cap rates largely reflects
its effect on prices. We regress cap rates on the peak ground acceleration (PGA), a measure of
quake intensity during the Northridge quake to measure the direct shaking effect of the Northridge
earthquake. To capture the indirect effects of the Northridge quake, we examine the interactions
of quake risk with the log of one plus the numb er of days following the Northridge quake on
which the transaction took place (for transactions within one year of the quake) and an indicator
for the year following the quake, and include the quake risk variable itself, which measures a
property’s susceptibility to future earthquake damage, irrespective of whether it was affected by
the January, 1994 quake. The Northridge earthquake served as a significant shock to the supply of
the catastrophe insurance, and our interaction variables measure the extent to which this shock had
a diminishing effect over time. We also include the log of the number of days following the quake
(for transactions within one year of the quake) as an additional control.
25
The standard controls
from the previous regressions, including census tract fixed effects, are included in the regression.
The first column of Table VII reports the results. Neither the PGA nor the interactions are
significant. The indirect effect of the earthquake seems to have been small, as quake risk did not
22
Comerio et al. (1996), Ong et al. (2003), Loukaitou-Sideris and Kamel (2004) discuss the effects of the Northridge
earthquake.
23
See, for example, Business Insurance, July 4, 1994 and Journal of Commerce, April 19, 1994.
24
As documented in the accounts in Business Insurance, August 29, 1994 and Journal of Commerce, October 25,
1996.
25
An indicator for the year following the quake is almost identical to the year indicator for 1994. Including it has
no effect on the regression results.
26
have a larger effect on property prices in the year after the Northridge quake.
26
Result 6 states that the probability of bank financing increases with insurance market compet-
itiveness. If the Northridge quake decreased the supply of catastrophe insurance, we should see
relatively less bank financing for high catastrophe risk properties in its aftermath. We test this
prediction by regressing the probability of bank financing on the previous set of variables for the
direct and indirect impact of the quake. We find, as detailed in column two of Table VII, that the
interaction of quake risk with the log of one plus the number of days after the quake (for properties
sold within a year of the quake) is positive and significant (t-statistic = 2.57). The interaction of
quake risk with an indicator for the year following the quake is negative and significant (t-statistic
= 2.31). The second interaction term indicates that shortly after the Northridge earthquake
properties with high earthquake risk were particularly unlikely to be financed with bank loans.
The first interaction term indicates that this effect moderated with time; as time passed the sup-
plementary post-Northridge negative effect of quake risk on bank financing subsided. Considering
the two interactions together, we find that the impact of the Northridge quake had essentially
dissipated 3 months after the event. These results are consistent with Result 6: the catastrophic
insurance supply shock generated by the Northridge quake reduced the provision of bank finance
for high quake risk properties for approximately 3 months. The Northridge quake, however, had
no significant long-term effect on the pricing or financing of quake risk. Consistent with this result,
Froot (2001) finds no long-term effect of the Northridge earthquake on catastrophe premiums.
Column 3 of Table VII shows no significant increase in the size of banks making loans to high-
quake-risk properties in Los Angeles county after January 1994. However, in column 4 we do find
that local banks in Los Angeles county increased their lending to high-risk properties only gradually
in the first two months following the Northridge earthquake.
Result 7 states that the average quake risk of bank-financed transactions is increasing in insur-
ance market competitiveness, while the average quake risk of all-cash transactions is independent
of insurance market conditions. To test these predictions, we regress the quake risk of all properties
on the log of one plus the number of days following the Northridge quake on which the transaction
took place (for transactions within one year of the quake), the PGA, and the standard controls.
The results are displayed in the first column of Table VI II. We find a positive and significant (t-
statistic = 1.93) coefficient on the log of one plus the number of days following the quake, indicating
26
Bleich (2003) finds a 1-2 year effect of the Northridge quake on prices, but he considers the impact of the quake
itself (i.e. PGA, which we control for), not the general quake risk that is our object of study.
27
that as the catastrophe insurance supply shock diminished, more high quake risk properties were
purchased. This is consistent with the theory, but Result 7 makes an even more precise prediction.
Specifically, the result states that the quake risk of bank financed properties should increase as a
supply sho ck recedes, while the quake risk of all-cash transactions will be unaffected. In the second
column of Table VIII, we repeat the previous regression for the subsample of bank financed prop-
erties. We find that the average quake risk of bank-financed transactions increased significantly
(t-statistic = 2.61) in the days following the quake. As shown in the third column of Table VIII,
however, there is no effect on the average quake risk of all-cash transactions. These results are
consistent with the predictions of Result 7.
A. Commercial Earthquake Insurance Market after the Northridge Earthquake
We find little additional effect of the Northridge earthquake on credit markets after a period of three
months following the event. This finding is consistent with the rebound in the commercial earth-
quake insurance market after the Northridge quake. The Northridge earthquake had dramatically
different impacts on the residential and commercial earthquake insurance markets in California.
In 1994 and 1995 insurers, who faced a state law requiring them to offer earthquake insurance
along with any homeowner’s policy, in many cases elected to stop offering any new homeowner’s
coverage rather than being forced to offer earthquake insurance on terms they deemed unfavorable.
In response, the state government established the California Earthquake Authority as a publicly
managed, largely privately funded organization that provides catastrophic residential earthquake
insurance. No comparable state-managed organization was founded in the commercial earthquake
insurance market.
In the aftermath of the Northridge earthquake, commercial earthquake insurers have increased
their sophistication and made greater use of global reinsurance markets (Risk Management Solu-
tions, 2004). The California Department of Insurance (2003) reports that in the period 1994-1999,
commercial earthquake insurance coverage in the state increased, while residential coverage sharply
decreased. In Los Angeles and Orange counties, for example, commercial coverage grew from a
PML of $11.1 billion in 1994 to $13.6 billion in 1999. Residential coverage fell from $2.8 billion to
$1.1 billion during the same time period. This reasonably quick return to health for the commer-
cial earthquake market is confirmed by the press accounts cited above and is consistent with the
short-term effects of the Northridge earthquake that we find in the data.
28
V. Catastrophic Risk and Finance: Broader Implications
The model in Section I highlights two aspects of the interaction between bank credit and catastrophic
risk insurance markets. First, banks are inefficient financiers of catastrophe-susceptible properties
because they are poor at liquidating devastatingly-damaged collateral and they do not specialize in
monitoring the implementation of safety-increasing investments. Second, due to insufficient capital
and market power by a small number of reinsurers, the catastrophe insurance market is inefficient.
These two features, as we will discuss below, are shared by a variety of catastrophic perils including
hurricane, terrorism and political risks. The theory implies that, as a consequence, in markets
affected by any of these hazards increased catastrophic risk will be associated with reduced bank
credit provision, decreased market participation by less wealthy investors and missed investment
and development opportunities.
Our empirical work on earthquake risks broadly supports the predictions of the theory. Earth-
quake data offer two advantages for testing the theory. First, earthquake risks have been quantified
clearly, which facilitates suitable tests. Second, earthquake risk exhibits significant highly localized
variability, which enables the inclusion of census tract fixed effects in the tests, thereby minimiz-
ing the impact of unobservables. Our findings from the earthquake tests show the relevance of the
theory and therefore support the application of the general theoretical predictions to other settings.
A. Hurricane Risk
Hurricane risk closely resembles that of earthquakes. Hurricanes, like earthquakes, cause terrible
damage to properties that can be mitigated by appropriate preventative investments. The supply
of hurricane insurance also exhibits inefficiencies similar to that of earthquake insurance (Froot,
2001). We should therefore expect hurricane risk to have a similar effects to that documented above
for earthquakes.
To expand the scope of our empirical tests, in this section we examine the impact of hurricane
risk on commercial property financing. The properties in our sample all face relatively low hurricane
risk (all properties save one are described by AIR as having the same average annual loss from
hurricanes: less than 0.1%).
27
AIR, however, also provided us with each property’s percentile
hurricane risk within its county and properties within Massachusetts, Maryland, Virginia, Texas,
Georgia, New York and the District of Columbia exhibit variation in this relative hurricane risk.
27
The Texas properties in the sample are largely located in Dallas and Austin, away from the coasts.
29
As an additional test of Result 2 relating catastrophe risk to the provision of bank financing,
we regress an indicator for whether a property was financed with a bank loan on the property’s
percentile hurricane risk within its county and the previous controls, including census tract fixed
effects. The results, as reported in column 1 on Table IX, show that the coefficient on hurricane
risk is insignificant. Given the generally low level of hurricane peril in our properties, this may
reflect a lack of localized variation in hurricane risk within our sample. We thus repeat the previous
regression, replacing the census tract fixed effects with zip code fixed effects. As displayed in column
2 of Table IX, in this specification the coefficient on hurricane risk is negative and significant (t-
statistic=-2.26), as predicted by Result 2. A one-standard deviation increase in relative hurricane
risk reduces the probability of bank financing by 2.3 percentage points.
Results 2 and 6 also link the effects of catastrophe risk on financing to the competitiveness of
the insurance market. Hurricane Andrew in 1992 had a dramatic effect on the supply of hurricane
insurance (Froot, 2001), but only two properties in our sample with hurricane risk were sold in
1992. As an alternative measure of supply shocks to the hurricane insurance market, we consider
the Guy Carpenter Catastrophe Insurance Price Index. This variable is limited in two respects.
First, variations in a price index may reflect changes in demand rather than supply. Second, the
index is national and conflates the prices of multiple types of catastrophe insurance. Nonetheless,
the national price of catastrophe insurance is probably a reasonable proxy for the cost of all types
of catastrophe insurance outside of markets such as the hurricane insurance market in Florida and
the earthquake insurance market in California. Those two markets are excluded from this test, so
we will proceed with the analysis despite the limitations of the variable. We regress an indicator
for whether a property was purchased with a bank loan on hurricane risk, hurricane risk interacted
with the Guy Carpenter Catastrophe Insurance Price Index, the previous controls and zip code
fixed effects. (The Guy Carpenter Catastrophe Insurance Price Index is an annual index, so, given
the use of year fixed effects, we do not include it in the regression.) As described in column 3
of Table IX, the interaction between hurricane risk and the catastrophe insurance price index is
negative and significant: hurricane risk reduces the probability of bank finance particularly in the
years during which catastrophe insurance is especially expensive. This is consistent with Results 2
and 6, and suggests that the theory helps to explain the effects of hurricane risk on credit markets.
Recent research (Trenberth et al., 2007) proposes that there has been an increase in very severe
tropical cyclones, hurricanes, typhoons and other weather events that may be linked to human-
30
generated changes in the environment. As a result, understanding the role of optimal hurricane
risk allocation is increasingly relevant.
B. Terrorism Risk
Terrorism risk shares the central characteristics of other catastrophic risks: enormous potential
damages, specialized safety investments and inefficient supply of insurance. After the Sept. 11, 2001
terrorist attacks on the U.S., insurers and reinsurers quickly began to exclude terrorism risk from
their policies (Hubbard, Deal and Hess, 2005). Consistent with the predictions of the theoretical
model, commercial lending and development in major cities were significantly reduced (Serio, 2004).
Terrorism risk is more difficult to optimally allocate than natural disaster risk for three reasons.
First, terrorism risk is much harder to quantify. This ambiguity may lead to reduced provision of
insurance (Hogarth and Kunreuther, 1985). Second, terrorism is endogenously determined by the
actions of human agents. The optimal allocation of risk usually involves redistribution and trading,
but in the case of terrorism risks this may lead to market manipulation (Poteshman, 2006). Third,
the scale of damages from an act of terror is potentially greater than from a natural disaster.
The U.S. government passed the Terrorism Risk Insurance Act (TRIA) in 2002 to address the
dislocations in the terrorism insurance market. TRIA requires insurers to offer terrorism coverage
and institutes federal cost-sharing for terrorism damages. TRIA’s proponents argue that it has cre-
ated price stability in the terrorism risk insurance market and led to increased use of the insurance
(Hubbard, Deal and Hess, 2005). TRIA was renewed in 2005 and is up for renewal in 2007. The
long-term inefficiencies in the supply of natural disaster catastrophic insurance and the arguments
given above for why terrorism is even more difficult to insure than earthquakes or hurricanes in-
dicate that the private market is unlikely to successfully supply sufficient terrorism insurance on
its own. The findings in this paper therefore suggest two implications of a failure to renew TRIA.
First, high profile properties and those located in high density areas (possible terrorism targets)
are likely to suffer from reduced bank credit provision and market exit by less wealthy investors.
Downtown areas in large U.S. cities would be predicted to exhibit a substantial shift away from
debt financing of properties and prices for larger properties may significantly decline. Second, rede-
velopment after an act of terrorism will hampered by a particularly restricted supply of bank credit
in the immediate post-event period. These effects will especially severe in minority neighborhoods.
31
C. Political Risk
The p olitical risk associated with an investment describes the probability of nationalization, cur-
rency controls or other government action that reduces the project value. This risk, which is
typically most salient in emerging markets, has the p otential to generate huge losses and the risk
assessment is uncertain, so the supply of political risk insurance, like that of other catastrophic
risks, is quite restricted (Hamdani et al., 2005). The providers of political risk insurance (particu-
larly the public agencies such as the Multilateral Investment Guarantee Agency of the World Bank
and the Overseas Private Development Corporation of the U.S. government) are typically skilled
at negotiating with the local authorities. In the terms of our model, these insurers are better at
liquidating investments adversely affected by catastrophic political risk.
Our model and empirical work indicate that p olitical risk insurance can serve two important
functions. First, our results tying investment and market participation to the efficiency of insurance
markets imply that more financially constrained and smaller firms will be significantly more likely
to invest in developing foreign countries if fairly priced political risk insurance is available. Second,
there is growing interest in emerging market debt (Erb, Harvey, Viskanta, 2000). Our findings
linking loan provision to the availability of catastrophic insurance suggest that investors will be more
willing to provide debt financing to at-risk firms when it is accompanied by political insurance.
28
This implies that a well-functioning political risk insurance market will be especially important in
promoting the issuance of emerging market corporate bonds.
VI. Conclusion
We present a model in which banks are inefficient in financing properties facing catastrophic risk
because they are poor at liquidating catastrophically-damaged properties and they do not special-
ize in monitoring the implementation of safety-improving investments. These functions are best
performed by insurers, but imperfections in the supply of catastrophe insurance can distort real
estate markets by limiting the provision of bank credit and preventing positive NPV projects from
being undertaken.
An empirical analysis of the effects of earthquake risk provides evidence in support of the
theory. We find that earthquake-prone properties are much less likely to be financed with bank
28
As our model makes clear, the inefficient liquidation problem faced by lenders may make them unwilling to supply
debt in the absence of insurance, irrespective of the promised interest rate. Alternatively, the lack of insurance may
increase the necessary promised rate to a level that borrowers regard as unacceptable.
32
debt, and we provide evidence that older properties, properties in African-American neighborhoods
and properties slated for development are all especially unlikely to receive bank financing in the
presence of earthquake risk. The financing of property purchases by insurance firms, that likely have
privileged access to earthquake coverage, is unaffected by earthquake risk. Non-corporate buyers
of high risk properties tend to come from wealthier areas. This evidence suggests that inefficiencies
in the catastrophe insurance market are reducing the provision of bank credit, limiting the market
participation of less wealthy investors and hampering neighborhood revitalization in disadvantaged
areas.
The 1994 Northridge earthquake led to a reduction in lending to high-risk properties, but this
effect persisted for only three months. We find no significant longer-term financing or pricing effects
arising from the Northridge earthquake. Thus the large shock to the supply of earthquake insurance
arising from the earthquake exacerbated the degree of inefficiency in the financing of earthquake
risk for only a short period of time.
Our model presents a framework for analyzing broad classes of catastrophic risks including
hurricane, terrorism and political perils, and our empirical work suggests implications for all these
markets. We show that hurricane risk, like that of earthquakes, reduces bank financing. We argue
that terrorism and political risk share the central features of natural disaster risk and may be even
more subject to an insufficient supply of insurance. Our findings suggest that a lack of terrorism
insurance is likely to cause a shift away from debt financing in downtown U.S. cities and to lead to
the exit from these areas of less wealthy investors. A restricted supply of political risk insurance
will discourage foreign investments by financially-constrained firms and depress emerging market
corporate bond issuance. Exposure to catastrophic risks, both natural and unnatural, continues
to grow due to population shifts to at-risk areas, global warming and changing political dynamics.
Continued inefficiencies in the sharing of catastrophic risks and their effects on broader capital
markets may have implications for long-term growth in a wide variety of countries.
33
REFERENCES
1. Anderson, Dan R., and Maurice Weinrobe, 1986, Mortgage Default Risks and the 1971 San
Fernando Earthquake, AREUA Journal, 14, 110-135.
2. Benmelech, Efraim, Mark Garmaise, and Tobias Moskowitz, 2005, Do liquidation values
affect financial contracts? Evidence from commercial loan contracts and zoning regulation,
Quarterly Journal of Economics, August, 2005, 1121-1153.
3. Bethoux, Nicole, Guy Ouillon and Marc Nicolas, 1998, The instrumental seismicity of the
Western Alps: spatio-temporal patterns analysed with the wavelet transform, Geophysical
Journal Internation, 135, 177-194.
4. Bleich, Donald, 2003, The reaction of multifamily capitalization rates to natural disasters,
The Journal of Real Estate Research, 25, 133-144.
5. Bolton, Patrick, and David Scharfstein, 1996, Optimal Debt Structure and the Number of
Creditors, Journal of Political Economy, 104, 1-26.
6. Burgess, Robin, and Rohini Pande, 2003, Do Rural Banks Matter? Evidence from the Indian
Social Banking Experiment, Working paper, London School of Economics.
7. California Department of Insurance, 2003, California Earthquake Zoning and Probable Max-
imum Loss Evaluation Program.
8. Cetorelli, Nicola, and Michele Gambera, 2001, Banking Market Structure, Financial De-
pendence and Growth: International Evidence from Industry Data, Journal of Finance 56,
617-648.
9. Chen, Jun, and Yongheng Deng, 2003, Commercial Mortgage Workout Strategy and Con-
ditional Default Probability: Evidence from Special Serviced CMBS Loans, Working Paper,
University of Southern California.
10. Ciochetti, Brian A., 1997, Loss Characteristics of Commercial Mortgage Foreclosures, Real
Estate Finance 97, 53-69.
11. Comerio Mary C., John D. Landis, Catherine J. Firpo and Juan Pablo Monzon, 1996, Res-
idential Earthquake Recovery: Improving Californias Post-Disaster Rebuilding Policies and
Programs, Working Paper, California Policy Seminar Brief Series.
34
12. Cotterman, Robert F., and James E. Pearce, 1996, The Effects of the Federal National
Mortgage Association and the Federal Home Loan Mortgage Corporation on Conventional
Fixed-Rate Mortgage Yields, in: U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development, ed.,
Studies on Privatizing Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac, U.S. Department of Housing and Urban
Development. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development.
13. Cummins, J. David, David Lalonde and Richard D. Phillips, 2004, The basis risk of catastrophic-
loss index securities, Journal of Financial Economics, 71, 77-111.
14. DiPasquale, D., and E. L. Glaeser, 1999, Incentives and Social Capital: Are Homeowners
Better Citizens?, Journal of Urban Economics 45, 35484.
15. Diamond, Douglas, 2004, Presidential Address, Committing to Commit: Short-term Debt
When Enforcement is Costly, Journal of Finance 59, 1447-1479.
16. Duffie, Darrell, and Kenneth J. Singleton, 1999, Modeling Term Structures of Defaultable
Bonds, Review of Financial Studies, 687-720.
17. Erb, Claude B., Campbell R. Harvey and Tadas E. Viskanta, 2000, Understanding Emerging
Market Bonds, Emerging Markets Quarterly 4, 1, 7-23.
18. Froot, Kenneth A., 2001, The market for catastrophe risk: a clinical examination, Journal of
Financial Economics, 60, 529-571.
19. Froot, Kenneth A., and Paul G.J. O’Connell, 1997. On the pricing of intermediated risks:
theory, and application to catastrophe reinsurance. NBER Working paper no. 6011.
20. Fudenberg, Drew, and Jean Tirole, 1993, Game Theory, MIT Press, Cambridge.
21. Garmaise, Mark J., and Tobias J. Moskowitz, 2003, “Informal Financial Networks: Theory
and Evidence,” Review of Financial Studies, 16, 1007-1040.
22. Garmaise, Mark J., and Tobias J. Moskowitz, 2004, “Confronting Information Asymmetries:
Evidence from Real Estate Markets,” Review of Financial Studies, 17, 405-437.
23. Garmaise, Mark J., and Tobias J. Moskowitz, 2005, Bank Mergers and Crime: The Real and
Social Effects of Credit Market Competition, Journal of Finance, forthcoming.
35
24. Glaeser, Edward L., and Hedi D. Kallal, 1997, Thin Markets, Asymmetric Information, and
Mortgage-Backed Securities, Journal of Financial Intermediation, 6, 64-86.
25. Glickman, Andrea, and Joshua Stein, 2005, Best practices in commercial real estate financing:
Insurance and commercial mortgages in the new world of risk, Briefings in Real Estate Finance
4, 309-317.
26. Hall, Brian J., and Kevin J. Murphy, 2000, Stock Options for Undiversified Executives, NBER
Working paper.
27. Hamdani, Kausar, 2005, Elise Liebers and George Zanjani, An Overview of Political Risk
Insurance, Federal Reserve Bank of New York Working Paper.
28. Hogath, Robin, and Howard Kunreuther, 1985, Ambiguity and Insurance Decisions, American
Economic Review 75, 386-390.
29. Hubbard, Glenn, Bruce Deal and Peter Hess, 2005, The Economic Effects of Federal Partici-
pation in Terrorism Risk, Risk Management and Insurance Review 8, 177-209.
30. Jaffee, Dwight M., and Thomas Russell, 1997, Catastrophe insurance, capital markets, and
uninsurable risks, Journal of Risk and Insurance 64, 205-230.
31. Loukaitou-Sideris, Anastasia, and Nabil M. Kamel, 2004, Residential Recovery from the
Northridge Earthquake: An Evaluation of Federal Assistance Programs, University of Cali-
fornia Working paper.
32. Kagan, Y. Y., 1997, Seismic moment-frequency relation for shallow earthquakes: Regional
comparison, Journal of Geophysical Research 102, 28352852.
33. Kane, Edward J., 1999, Housing Finance GSEs: Who Gets the Subsidy?, Journal of Financial
Services Research, 15, 197-209.
34. Klein, Michael, Joe Peek and Eric Rosengren, 2002, Troubled Banks, Impaired Foreign In-
vestment: The Role of Relative Access to Credit, American Economic Review 92, 664-682.
35. Kwast, Myron L., Martha Starr-McCluer, and John D. Wolken, 1997, Market Definition and
the Analysis of Antitrust in Banking, Antitrust Bulletin 42, 973-95.
36
36. MacDonald, Gordon J., 2000, A Note on Order Statistics and Property Losses from Catastrophic
Hurricanes and Floods in the USA, Interim Report 00-047, International Institute for Applied
Systems Analysis.
37. Munnell, Alicia H., Geoffrey M. B. Tootell, Lynn E. Browne and James McEneaney, 1996,
Mortgage Lending in Boston: Interpreting HMDA Data, American Economic Review, 86,
25-53.
38. Nakagawa, Masayuki, Makoto Saito and Hisaki Yamaga, 2004, Earthquake Risks and Land
Prices: Evidence from the Tokyo Metropolitan Area, Nihon University Working paper.
39. Nakagawa, Masayuki, Makoto Saito and Hisaki Yamaga, 2005, Earthquake Risk and Housing
Rents: Evidence from the Tokyo Metropolitan Area, Univesity of Tsukuba Working paper.
40. Niehaus, Greg, 2002, The allocation of catastrophe risk, Journal of Banking and Finance, 26,
585-596.
41. Ong, Paul, James Spencer, Michela Zonta, Todd Nelson, Douglas Miller and Julia Heintz-
Mackoff, 2003, The Economic Cycle and Los Angeles Neighborhoods; 1987-2001, University
of California Working paper.
42. Otani, Shunsuke, 2000, Seismic Vulnerability Assessment of Reinforced Concrete Buildings,
The Journal of the Faculty of Engineering, University of Tokyo, Series B 47, 5 - 28.
43. Peek, Joe, and Eric Rosengren, 2000, Collateral Damage: Effects of the Japanese Bank Crisis
on Real Activity in the United States, American Economic Review 90, 30-45.
44. Petak, William J., and Shirin Elahi, 2000, The Northridge Earthquake, USA and Its Economic
and Social Impacts, Euroconference on Global Change and Catastrophe Risk Management:
Earthquake Risks in Europe, International Institute for Applied Systems Analysis (IIASA),
128.
45. Porter, Keith A., James L. Beck, Rustem V. Shaikhutdinov, Siu Kui Au, Kaoru Mizukoshi,
Masamitsu Miyamura, Hiroshi Ishida, Takafumi Moroi, Yasu Tsukada and Manabu Masudai,
2004, Earthquake Spectra 20, 12111237.
46. Poteshman, Allen M., 2006, Unusual Option Market Activity and the Terrorist Attacks of
September 11, 2001, Journal of Business 79, 1703-1726.
37
47. Risk Management Solutions, 2004, The Northridge, California Earthquake: RMS 10-Year
Retrospective.
48. Rohe, William M., Shannon Van Zandt and George McCarthy, 2000, The Social Benefits and
Costs of Homeownership: a Critical Assessment of the Research, Working paper, Research
Institute for Housing America.
49. Roll, Richard, 2003, Benefits to Homeowners from Mortgage Portfolios Retained by Fannie
Mae and Freddie Mac, Journal of Financial Services Research, 23, 29-42.
50. Ross, Stephen L., and Geoffrey M.B. Tootell, 2004, Redlining, the Community Reinvestment
Act, and Private Mortgage Insurance, Journal of Urban Economics, 55, 278-297.
51. Roth, Richard J., 1998, Earthquake insurance in California, in: Howard Kunreuther and
Richard J. Roth, eds., Paying the Price: The Status and Role of Insurance Against Natural
Disasters in the United States. Washington, D.C.: Joseph Henry Press.
52. R¨uttener, Erik, Dany Liechti and Stephan Eugster, 1999, The Risk Premium Distribution
(Average Annual Loss) with Respect to Earthquake Magnitude, XXIV European Geophysical
Society General Assembly.
53. Schulze, William D., David S. Brookshire, Ronda K. Hageman and John Tschirhart, 1987,
Benefits and Costs of Earthquake Resistant Buildings, Southern Economic Journal, 53, 934-
951.
54. Serio, Gregory, 2004, Statement of New York State Insurance Department before U.S. House
of Representatives Subcommittee on Capital Markets, Insurnace, and Government Sponsored
Enterprises and the Subcommittee on Oversight and Investigations.
55. Shah, Haresh, and Daniel Rosenbaum, 1996, Earthquake Risk Shakes Mortgage Industry,
Secondary Mortgage Markets 13, 12-19.
56. Smith, Clifford, and Jerold Warner, 1979, On Financial Contracting - An Analysis of Bond
Covenants, Journal of Financial Economics 7, 117-161.
57. Squires, Gregory D., Sally O’Connor and Josh Silver, 2001, The Unavailability of Information
on Insurance Unavailability: Insurance Redlining and the Absence of Geocoded Disclosure
Data, Housing Policy Debate, 12, 347-372.
38
58. Squires, Gregory D., 2003, Racial Profiling, Insurance Style: Insurance Redlining and the
Uneven Development of Metropolitan Areas, Journal of Urban Affairs, 25, 391-410.
59. Standand and Poor’s, 2003, U.S. CMBS Legal and Structured Finance Criteria.
60. Thomas, Jerry L., 1997, Testimony before the Subcommiteee on Housing and Community
Oppurtunity, Committee on Banking and Financial Services, U.S. House of Representatives.
61. Trenberth, K.E., P.D. Jones, P. Ambenje, R. Bojariu, D. Easterling, A. Klein Tank, D.
Parker, F. Rahimzadeh, J.A. Renwick, M. Rusticucci, B. Soden and P. Zhai, 2007, Observa-
tions: Surface and Atmospheric Climate Change. In: Climate Change 2007: The Physical
Science Basis. Contribution of Working Group I to the Fourth Assessment Report of the
Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change [Solomon, S., D. Qin, M. Manning, Z. Chen,
M. Marquis, K.B. Averyt, M. Tignor and H.L. Miller (eds.)]. Cambridge University Press,
Cambridge, United Kingdom and New York, NY, USA.
62. Vandell, Kerry D., 1998, Strategic Management of the Apartment Business in a “Big REIT”
World, National Multi Housing Council Working paper.
63. Zanjani, George, 2002, Pricing and capital allocation in catastrophe insurance, Journal of
Financial Economics, 65, 283-305.
Appendix
We propose (and later confirm) that V
t
= kC
t
for some constant k. Under this assumption V
t
has
the same risk as C
t
and may also be discounted at the rate r. The value of the property at any
given time s must satisfy:
V
s
= p
E[C
s+1
+ V
s+1
|C
s
]
1 + r
+ (1 p)
E [R
s+1
V
s+1
|C
s
]
1 + r
. (3)
The equations V
x
= kC
x
and E[C
x+1
|C
x
] = C
x
for all x then imply that
kC
s
= p
(1 + k)C
s
1 + r
+ (1 p)
E[R]kC
s
1 + r
,
which simplifies to
k(1 + r p (1 p)E[R]) = p. (4)
39
This equation shows that k is a constant, so the valuation equation (3) is indeed satisfied by our
proposed solution V
t
= kC
t
.
Proof of Result 1:
The cap rate is
1
k
=
r+q
p
. We calculate
d
³
1
k
´
dq
=
1
p
(r + q)
dp
dq
1.
Model of Inefficient Liquidation by Banks of Catastrophe-damaged properties
We presume that banks do not observe R
t
and they are incapable of undertaking repairs on
their own. Consequently, if banks seize a property in default that is damaged in a catastrophe,
a fraction δ (0, 1) of its value is destroyed in liquidation. For example, we may assume that
there is limited liquidity for damaged properties (particularly after a catastrophe) and banks must
hold these impaired (and non-cash-flow-producing) properties for several periods before they can
be sold.
We assume that when a bank provides a mortgage in perio d s with promised repayment m
in the following period, it receives min{m, C
s+1
+ V
s+1
} if there is no catastrophe. That is, we
assume that loans are non-recourse (as is the case for our sample of commercial real estate loans),
and for simplicity, we presume that there are no liquidation costs for the bank in the absence of
a catastrophe; the bank can simply sell a defaulted property on the open market. In the event of
a catastrophe, the bank does not observe the current value of the property, because it does not
observe R
s
+1
. We assume that the bank makes a take-it-or-leave-it offer to the property owner,
demanding m
1
m in repayment. If m
1
< m, the bank negotiates terms by forgiving part of its
loan.
29
We presume that the banking sector is competitive; our focus is on credit market distortions
that are related to catastrophic risk, rather than general credit market distortions.
The property owner does observe R
s+1
. If the property owner remains in possession of the
property, he can repair it at a cost of (1 R
s+1
)V
s+1
and then sell the property for V
s+1
.
30
The
property owner will only accept the bank’s offer if his net proceeds after repairing the property
exceed m
1
. (If a portion of the repair costs are effort costs borne by the owner, then the owner
will strictly prefer to reject bank offers that are too high.) That is, the bank’s offer will only be
accepted if
29
Chen and Deng (2003) show that loan workouts with modified loan terms are common in commercial real estate.
30
The repair can be financed by a bank that makes a top priority loan that is verifiably invested in the property.
Since the repair is positive net present value, the bank will be repaid.
40
V
s+1
R
s+1
m
1
.
If the owner rejects the bank’s offer, then the bank receives δV
s+1
. We set f
R
and F
R
to
be the probability density function (pdf) and cumulative distribution function (cdf) of the {R
s
},
respectively. The bank chooses m
1
to maximize
max
m
1
m
m
1
µ
1 F
R
µ
m
1
V
s+1
¶¶
+ (1 δ)
Z
m
1
0
f
R
µ
r
V
s+1
r
V
s+1
dr (5)
Equivalently, the bank solves
max
x
m
V
s+1
V
s+1
·
x (1 F
R
(x)) + (1 δ)
Z
x
0
f
R
(r)rdr
¸
(6)
We will presume that the {R
s
} have support [0, 1] and satisfy the monotone-hazard-rate property
(i.e.,
d
dx
³
f
R
(x)
1F
R
(x)
´
0) to guarantee that there is a unique interior solution to (6). The monotone-
hazard-rate (MHR) condition is satisfied by the uniform, truncated normal, truncated exponential
and many other distribution functions (Fudenberg and Tirole, p.267).
We define L(m, V, p) to be the current market value of a one-period mortgage with promised
repayment m secured against a prop erty with value V and catastrophe frequency (1 p). We
first show that catastrophe risk reduces the value of a loan. As the frequency of the catastrophe
increases, conditions A and B guarantee that the property’s payoff next period will be more risky.
This risk is, of course, incorporated in the current property value, for a given value today of V , an
increase in catastrophe risk leads to a higher payoff if no catastrophe occurs, but a lower payoff in
the event of a catastrophe. The net impact is to reduce the value of a given mortgage claim.
Lemma 1. The market value of a mortgage with a given promised repayment is decreasing in
the underlying asset’s catastrophe risk. Formally, L(m, V, p) is increasing in p.
Proof of Lemma 1. For a given current (i.e., period s ) property market value V
s
, we denote
by ² the risk-neutral probability associated with next period’s market value V
s+1
, and we define r
f
to be the risk-free rate. We set d(m, V
s+1
, p) to be equal to the payoff received by the debtholder
in perio d s + 1 when the promised repayment is m and the property value is V
s+1
. We will show
that for any outcome of V
s+1
, d(m, V
s+1
, p) is increasing in p. We let p
1
p
2
be given. We have
C
s
(p) = V
s
µ
r + (1 p)(1 E[R])
p
.
41
The function C
s
is decreasing in p. We first suppose that m V
s+1
+C
s+1
(p
2
) V
s+1
+C
s+1
(p
1
).
The derivative of the objective function in (6) with respect to x is
V
s+1
(1 F
R
(x) δf
R
(x)x) .
The MHR property guarantees that there is a unique value x
(0, 1) that maximizes the
unconstrained objective function in (6). Since m V
s+1
, for both p
1
and p
2
, in the event of a
catastrophe the bank will solve the unconstrained problem and set x = x
. We define
λ =
h
x
(1 F
R
(x
)) + (1 δ)
R
x
0
f
R
(r)rdr
i
E[R]
(0, 1).
In the non-catastrophe states, the bank will receive the full cash flows and property value. We
thus have for i = 1, 2
d(m, V
s+1
, p
i
) = p
i
(V
s+1
+ C
s+1
(p
i
)) + (1 p)V
s+1
λE[R]
= V
s+1
(r + q(p
i
) + p
i
+ (1 p
i
)λE[R])
= V
s+1
(r + 1 (1 p
i
)E[R](1 λ)) .
It is clear that d(m, V
s+1
, p
1
) d(m, V
s+1
, p
2
). For m [V
s+1
+ C
s+1
(p
1
), V
s+1
+ C
s+1
(p
2
)],
d(m, V
s+1
, p
1
) is constant, while d(m, V
s+1
, p
2
) = p
2
m + (1 p)V
s+1
λE[R] is increasing, so the
result just shown also demonstrates that d(m, V
s+1
, p
1
) d(m, V
s+1
, p
2
) on this range. Last, we
consider m < V
s+1
+ C
s+1
(p
1
). If there is no catastrophe, the lender receives m under both p
1
and
p
2
. Now suppose there is a catastrophe. We have
F
R
µ
m
1
V
s+1
F
R
µ
m
1
V
s+1
so V
s+1
R
s+1
dominates V
s+1
R
s+1
in the sense of first-order stochastic dominance. For each
choice of m
1
, the objective function in (5) is the expectation of an increasing function of V
s+1
R
s+1
.
The first-order stochastic dominance relationship shows that for any choice m, the payoff to the
lender under p
1
exceeds that under p
2
. The payoff to the lender under the optimal choice of m
must therefore be higher under p
1
. We denote the payoff to the lender under the optimal choice by
y(p
i
) for i {1, 2}. We have y(p
2
) y(p
1
) m. We conclude that
m(p
1
p
2
) y(p
1
)(p
1
p
2
) (1 p
2
)y(p
2
) (1 p
1
)y(p
1
)
42
p
1
m + (1 p
1
)y(p
1
) p
2
m + (1 p
2
)y(p
2
) d(m, V
s+1
, p
1
) d(m, V
s+1
, p
2
).
We therefore have d(m, V
s+1
, p
1
) d(m, V
s+1
, p
2
) for all V
s+1
, so
L(m, V
s
, p
1
) =
R
d(m, V
s+1
, p
1
)²(V
s+1
)dV
s+1
1 + r
f
R
d(m, V
s+1
, p
2
)²(V
s+1
)dV
s+1
1 + r
f
= L(m, V
s
, p
2
).
We define the debt capacity DC of a property to be the maximum loan value that can be
secured by the property. That is, DC(V
s
, p) = L(, V
s
, p). We now consider the payoff of the
prospective buyer with a private benefit. The investor will receive his private benefit and an equity
claim on the property in exchange for his cash investment. We define Π
B
(w, V
s
, p) to be the net
present value received by this investor if he invests w V
s
in cash and borrows V
s
w in order to
purchase a property with catastrophe frequency (1 p).
For w V
s
, the investor with a private benefit requires a loan with value dval = V
s
w. The
value of the investor’s equity claim is equal to the value V
s
of the property minus the value of
the bank’s debt claim minus any value destroyed in inefficient liquidation. If DC(V
s
, p) + w V
s
,
the debt financing is possible, and we denote the value of inefficient liquidation by loss(w, V
s
, p).
For notational convenience we set loss(w, V
s
, p) = when debt financing is not possible. Credit
markets are competitive, so the bank’s debt claim has a value of dval. When debt financing is
feasible, the net present value of the investor’s investment is therefore equal to his private benefit
minus the value destroyed in inefficient liquidation. Since not investing is always an option, we
have
Π
B
(w, V
s
, p) = max{b + (V
s
L(m, V
s
, p) loss(w, V
s
, p)) w, 0},
where m is such that L(m, V
s
, p) = V
s
w. Thus
Π
B
(w, V
s
, p) = max{b loss(w, V
s
, p), 0}.
Lemma 2. Debt capacity decreases with catastrophe risk: DC(V
s
, p) is increasing in p. The
prospective buyer’s net present value is decreasing in catastrophe risk and increasing in his cash
investment. Formally, Π
B
(w, V
s
, p) is increasing in p and w.
Proof of Lemma 2. We have m = , so m V
s+1
. Following the proof of Lemma 1, for all
V
s+1
43
d(, V
s+1
, p) = V
s+1
(r + 1 (1 p)E[R](1 λ)) ,
which is increasing in p. This shows that debt capacity is increasing in p.
For w V
s
, the investor with a private benefit requires a loan with value k = V
s
w. We define
m(w, V
s
, p) to be the m such that L(m, V
s
, p) = V
s
w, if it exists. Our result on debt capacity shows
that as p increases it is more likely that the project can be financed. Thus, Π
B
(w, V
s
, p) = 0 for p
and w so low that DC(V
s
, p)+w < V
s
. Consider p and w such that the project can be financed. It is
clear from (5) that L(m, V
s
, p) is increasing in m and Lemma 1 shows that L(m, V
s
, p) is increasing
in p. This implies that m(w, V
s
, p) is decreasing in p and w.
We now consider the optimal loan forgiveness strategy of the bank. We denote by ˆx(w, V
s
, V
s+1
, p)
the value of x that solves the problem (6) for a given V
s+1
,p and m = m(w, V
s
, p). We have that
m(w,V
s
,p)
V
s+1
is decreasing in both p and w. That shows that ˆx(w, V
s
, V
s+1
, p) is decreasing in p and w.
loss(w, V
s
, p) =
δ(1 p)
R
V
s+1
R
ˆx(w,V
s
,V
s+1
,p)
0
f
R
(r)rdr²(V
s+1
)dV
s+1
1 + r
f
.
The fact that ˆx(w, V
s
, V
s+1
, p) is decreasing in p and w shows that loss(w, V
s
, p) is decreasing
in p and w (Property 1).
For debt with any face value m > 0 and p < 1, the liquidation costs may be written as
δ(1 p)
R R
min{
m
V
s+1
,x
}
0
f
R
(r)rdrV
s+1
²(V
s+1
)dV
s+1
1 + r
f
, (7)
which is strictly positive since f
r
has support [0, 1] (Property 2).
Proof of Result 2. If the investor is unconstrained, the transaction is consummated in all
cases in an all-cash deal. If the investor is constrained, he will only purchase the property with a
bank loan. There are three possibilities. With probability (1n)
2
, no insurers bid and the investor
purchases the property only if b loss(w, V
s
, p). In this case the property is purchased without
insurance. With probability 2n(1n) one insurer bids, the bid is sur = min{b
, w
L
, loss(w
L
, V
s
, p)},
and the investor purchases the property only if b min{b
, w
L
, loss(w
L
, V
s
, p)}. In this case the
property is purchased with insurance. With probability n
2
, two insurers bid, sur = 0 and the
investor always purchases the property with insurance. Thus probability that a transaction is
financed with bank debt is given by
44
(1 l)
¡
(1 n)
2
(1 F
b
(loss(w, V
s
, p))) + 2n(1 n)(1 F
b
(min{b
, w
L
, loss(w
L
, V
s
, p)})) + n
2
¢
(1 l) ((1 n)
2
(1 F
b
(loss(w, V
s
, p))) + 2n(1 n)(1 F
b
(min{b
, w
L
, loss(w
L
, V
s
, p)})) + n
2
) + l
.
(8)
The result follows Property 1 that loss(w
L
, V
s
, p) is decreasing in p.
Proof of Result 3.
The average wealth of the purchasing investor is given by
w
L
(1 l)
¡
(1 n)
2
(1 F
b
(loss(w, V
s
, p))) + 2n(1 n)(1 F
b
(min{b
, w
L
, loss(w
L
, V
s
, p)})) + n
2
¢
+ w
H
l
(1 l) ((1 n)
2
(1 F
b
(loss(w, V
s
, p))) + 2n(1 n)(1 F
b
(min{b
, w
L
, loss(w
L
, V
s
, p)})) + n
2
) + l
.
(9)
The result follows Property 1.
Proof of Result 4. If the insurance market is perfectly competitive, insurance is provided at
fair value, and purchasing insurance allows the constrained investor to avoid all liquidation costs.
For debt with any face value m > 0, if (1 p) > 0 Property 2 shows that these liquidation costs
are strictly positive, so all constrained investors will purchase insurance. If the insurance market
is imperfectly competitive, the proof of Result 2 showed that the probability that a bank-financed
purchase carries insurance is given by
¡
2n(1 n)(1 F
b
(min{b
, w
L
, loss(w
L
, V
s
, p)})) + n
2
¢
((1 n)
2
(1 F
b
(loss(w, V
s
, p))) + 2n(1 n)(1 F
b
(min{b
, w
L
, loss(w
L
, V
s
, p)})) + n
2
)
. (10)
The result follows from the fact that loss(w
L
, V
s
, p) is decreasing in p.
Proof of Result 5. The probability of a transaction is given by
(1l)
³
(1 n)
2
(1 F
b
(loss(w, V
s
, p))) + 2n(1 n)(1 F
b
(min{b
, w
L
, loss(w
L
, V
s
, p)})) + n
2
´
+l.
The result follows from the fact that loss(w
L
, V
s
, p) is decreasing in p.
We now assess the impact on a change in the competitiveness of the insurance market in the
composition of properties sold in the market. We suppose that p is a random variable with cdf F
P
and pdf f
P
.
Proof of Result 6. The result follows from (8) and from the fact that for 1 b a,
d
dn
(a(1 n)
2
+ 2bn(1 n) + n
2
) = 2(n nb + b(1 n) a(1 n)) 0.
45
Proof of Result 7. Unconstrained investors pay all cash and do not suffer liquidation costs,
so the average catastrophic risk of all-cash transactions is E[1 p]. Constrained investors require
bank financing. The pdf h
1
(p, n) of bank-financed sales for a given n is
h
1
(p, n)
=
f
P
(p)
¡
(1 n)
2
(1 F
b
(loss(w
L
, V
s
, p))) + 2n(1 n)(1 F
b
(min{b
, w
L
, loss(w
L
, V
s
, p)})) + n
2
¢
R
f
P
(x) ((1 n)
2
(1 F
b
(loss(w
L
, V
s
, p))) + 2n(1 n)(1 F
b
(min{b
, w
L
, loss(w
L
, V
s
, p)})) + n
2
) dx
We will show that for n
1
n
2
, h
1
(p, n
2
) dominates h
1
(p, n
1
) in the sense of the monotone like-
lihood ratio property (MLRP). That is sufficient to show
R
(1 p)h
1
(p, n
1
)dp
R
(1 p)h
1
(p, n
2
)dp.
We require that
r(p) =
(1 n
1
)
2
(1 F
b
(loss(w
L
, V
s
, p))) + 2n
1
(1 n
1
)(1 F
b
(min{b
, w
L
, loss(w
L
, V
s
, p)})) + n
2
1
(1 n
2
)
2
(1 F
b
(loss(w
L
, V
s
, p))) + 2n
2
(1 n
2
)(1 F
b
(min{b
, w
L
, loss(w
L
, V
s
, p)})) + n
2
2
be decreasing in p. We first note that
r
1
(p) =
Aj
1
(p) + B
Cj
1
(p) + D
(11)
is decreasing in p if j
1
(p) is increasing in p and
B
D
A
C
. For p such that loss(w
L
, V
s
, p)
min{b
, w
L
}, r(p) =
Aj
1
(p)+B
Cj
1
(p)+D
, where j
1
(p) = 1F
b
(loss(w
L
, V
s
, p)) is increasing in p and
B
D
=
n
2
1
n
2
2
1
1n
2
1
1n
2
2
=
A
C
. For p such that loss(w
L
, V
s
, p) min{b
, w
L
} but such that loss(w
L
, V
s
, p) <
(i.e. such that loss(w
L
, V
s
, p) w
L
), r(p) =
Aj
1
(p)+B
Cj
1
(p)+D
, where j
1
(p) = 1 F
b
(loss(w
L
, V
s
, p)) and
B
D
=
n
2
1
+2n
1
(1n
1
)(1F
b
(min{b
,w
L
}))
n
2
2
+2n
2
(1n
2
)(1F
b
(min{b
,w
L
}))
1
(1n
1
)
2
(1n
2
)
2
=
A
C
. The function r is discontinuous at p
such
that loss(w
L
, V
s
, p
) = w
L
. We note, however, that for p < p
,
r(p) =
2n
1
(1 n
1
)(1 F
b
(min{b
, w
L
})) + n
2
1
2n
2
(1 n
2
)(1 F
b
(min{b
, w
L
})) + n
2
2
(1 n
1
)
2
(1 F
b
(w
L
)) + 2n
1
(1 n
1
)(1 F
b
(min{b
, w
L
})) + n
2
1
(1 n
2
)
2
(1 F
b
(w
L
)) + 2n
2
(1 n
2
)(1 F
b
(min{b
, w
L
})) + n
2
2
= r(p
)
since
n
2
1
+2n
1
(1n
1
)(1F
b
(min{b
,w
L
}))
n
2
2
+2n
2
(1n
2
)(1F
b
(min{b
,w
L
}))
1
(1n
1
)
2
(1n
2
)
2
.
46
Table I:
Summary Statistics of Commercial Real Estate Property Transactions,
Quake Risk, the Effects of the Northridge 1994 Earthquake,
and CMBS Issuances
Panel A: Summary statistics of COMPS sale and loan transactions
Standard
Mean Median deviation 1
st
% 99
th
%
Sale price ($US) 2,204,878 590,000 10,609,900 112,000 30,047,860
Capitalization rate (%) 10.02 9.75 2.81 4.57 18.35
Property age (years) 37.74 31 32.95 1 109
Loan size (% of price) 75.49 77.27 16.28 17.24 100
Interest rate (%) 8.28 8.25 1.41 5 12
Maturity (years) 16.06 15 10.79 0.50 30
Panel B: Summary statistics of COMPS quake risk and Northridge PGA
Standard
Mean Median Deviation
Quake risk - all properties 0.07 0 0.12
Quake risk - CA properties 0.19 0.20 0.12
Quake risk - LA county properties 0.25 0.20 0.07
Northridge PGA - all properties 7.71 0 14.13
Northridge PGA - CA properties 20.46 18.72 16.40
Northridge PGA - LA county properties 26.78 23.08 13.52
Panel C: Summary statistics of S&P CMBS Transactions
Number
CMBS issuers 24
CMBS transactions 50
Individual properties 482
High PML properties 183
Insured properties 169
Insured High PML properties 98
Panel A reports the distributional characteristics of the property transactions in the COMPS database over the
period January 1, 1992 to March 30, 1999. The mean, median, standard deviation, and one and 99 percentiles
of sale price, capitalization rate (net operating income divided by sales price), property age, loan size (loan-
to-value), loan interest rate, and loan maturity are reported. Panel B reports the mean, median and standard
deviation of average annual loss due to earthquake risk (quake risk) from the AIR database and peak ground
acceleration (PGA) during the Northridge (1994) earthquake from the USGS database across all properties in
the COMPS database. Panel C reports the number of commercial mortgage-backed securities (CMBS) issuers,
total CMBS transactions, total number of earthquake zone properties included in the CMBS transactions, the
number of earthquake zone properties with probable maximum loss above 20% (High PML), the number of
earthquake zone properties with earthquake insurance and the number of insured High PML properties.
47
Table II:
Earthquake Risk and Insurance for Securitized Loans
Dependent variable Quake insurance Quake insurance Quake insurance
provided? provided? provided?
N 482 482 482
High quake risk 1.51 1.41 1.00
(7.41) (2.55) (3.04)
[35.9%] [33.8%] [24.4%]
Fixed effects?
Year Yes Yes Yes
CMBS issuer No Yes No
CMBS transaction No No Yes
Estimation method Logit Logit Logit
R
2
0.09 0.09 0.02
Results from the regressions of an indicator for whether earthquake insurance was pro-
vided for the property securing the loan on an indicator for properties with probable
maximum loss above 20% (High PML), year dummies and transaction attributes. The
data is drawn from the S&P CMBS transactions database. The regressions are estimated
via binary fixed effects (conditional) logistic regression (Logit), as described, with robust
t-statistics reported in parentheses. The increase in probability of earthquake insurance
being provided for High quake risk properties (relative to the mean probability) in given
in square brackets. The reported R
2
is McFadden’s pseudo R
2
.
48
Table III:
Earthquake Risk and Commercial Real Estate Financing Terms
Dep endent variable Bank loan Interest Leverage Seller financing
provided? rate provided?
Sample All Bank loans Bank loans All
N 32,618 3,943 11,478 32,618
Quake Risk -2.6313 0.8337 -0.0279 0.7689
(-2.83) (0.64) (-0.33) (0.74)
Brokered 0.5620 -0.0207 0.0001 -0.2947
(18.62) (-0.35) (0.04) (-8.16)
Broker Buyer 0.1520 -0.0395 -0.0009 0.3684
(1.76) (-0.38) (-0.10) (3.87)
Log (Price) -0.0094 -0.0144 0.0142 -0.2294
(-0.61) (-0.42) (3.39) (-11.07)
Corporate Buyer -0.1878 0.0415 0.0001 -0.2287
(-5.59) (0.63) (1.15) (-5.46)
Property Crime -0.0002 -0.0015 0.0000 -0.0020
(-0.27) (-1.02) (-0.57) (-2.56)
Personal Crime -0.0002 0.0015 0.0001 0.0016
(-0.44) (1.35) (1.08) (2.20)
Age -0.0017 -0.0001 -0.0027 0.0066
(-2.93) (-0.20) (-2.76) (7.90)
Log (Buyer Distance) -0.0908 -0.0103 0.0013 -0.1056
(-12.70) (-0.74) (1.66) (-11.52)
Log (Seller Distance) -0.0002 0.0187 0.0160 -0.0291
(-0.02) (1.62) (1.57) (-3.67)
Development 0.0541 0.1852 -0.0001 -0.0350
(0.80) (1.10) (-0.73) (-0.41)
Maturity -0.0101 0.0024
(-4.18) (1.00)
Floating? -0.3463 0.0841
(-5.89) (6.91)
SBA? -0.3900
(-1.19)
Loan Size/Price -0.3771
(-1.65)
Log(Bank Assets) -0.0605 -0.0009
(-6.14) (-1.39)
Fixed effects?
Census tract Yes Yes Yes Yes
Year Yes Yes Yes Yes
Property type Yes Yes Yes Yes
Estimation method Logit OLS OLS Logit
R
2
0.19 0.72 0.32 0.12
Results from the regressions of an indicator for whether a bank loan was provided (first column),
the interest rate on an extended bank loan (second column), the leverage (loan size divided by
sale price) on an extended bank loan (third column) and an indicator for whether seller financing
was provided (fourth column) on quake risk and property and transaction attributes. The data
is drawn from the COMPS database. The regressors with reported coefficients are the average
annual loss due to earthquake risk (obtained from AIR), indicators for whether a broker arranged
the transaction and for whether the buyer was a broker, the log of the sale price (excluded from
the leverage regression), an indicator for corporate buyers, the 1990 property and personal crime
risks (obtained from CAP Index), the age of the property, the log of buyer and seller distances
from the property, an indicator for development projects, loan maturity in years, indicators for
floating rate and Small-Business-Administration guaranteed loans, leverage and log of bank assets.
All regressions include fixed effects for property type, year and census tract, with coefficients unre-
ported for brevity. The regressions are estimated via binary logistic regression (Logit) or ordinary
least squares (OLS), as described, with robust t-statistics reported in parentheses. Reported R
2
for Logit specifications is McFadden’s pseudo R
2
.
49
Table IV:
Cross-sectional Effects of Earthquake Risk on Provision of Financing
Dependent variable Bank loan Bank loan Bank loan Bank loan
provided? provided? provided? provided?
Sample All Age Tract value All
available available
N 32,618 25,012 25,752 32,618
Quake Risk -2.6626 -0.8694 -0.4747 -2.5873
(-2.86) (-0.86) (-0.21) (-2.78)
(Quake Risk) * (Insurance Firm) 5.6787
(2.20)
(Quake Risk) * Age -0.0540
(-8.62)
(Quake Risk) *(% African-American) -54.0184
(-2.30)
(Quake Risk)*Log (Tract Median Income) 0.0000
(-0.11)
(Quake Risk) * Development -2.1183
(-3.20)
Insurance Firm -1.4721
(-4.21)
Brokered 0.5615 0.5900 0.6260 0.5605
(18.60) (16.92) (17.98) (18.57)
Broker Buyer 0.1502 0.1682 0.1195 0.1507
(1.74) (1.64) (1.12) (1.74)
Log (Price) -0.0067 -0.0416 0.0137 -0.0095
(-0.43) (-2.31) (0.73) (-0.61)
Corporate Buyer -0.1903 -0.2187 -0.2400 -0.1856
(-5.66) (-5.55) (-6.10) (-5.52)
Property Crime -0.0002 -0.0003 -0.0003 -0.0002
(-0.26) (-0.38) (-0.36) (-0.28)
Personal Crime -0.0002 -0.0004 0.0000 -0.0002
(-0.44) (-0.61) (-0.01) (-0.42)
Age -0.0017 -0.0006 -0.0014 -0.0017
(-2.92) (-1.00) (-2.44) (-2.90)
Log (Buyer Distance) -0.0903 -0.0884 -0.0849 -0.0908
(-12.61) (-10.83) (-10.07) (-12.68)
Log (Seller Distance) -0.0005 -0.0010 -0.0046 -0.0001
(-0.07) (-0.13) (-0.62) (-0.01)
Development 0.0539 -0.0025 0.0344 0.1633
(0.80) (-0.03) (0.42) (2.16)
Fixed effects?
Census tract Yes Yes Yes Yes
Year Yes Yes Yes Yes
Property type Yes Yes Yes Yes
Estimation method Logit Logit Logit Logit
R
2
0.19 0.16 0.20 0.19
Results from the regressions of an indicator for whether a bank loan was provided on quake risk and property and
transaction attributes. The data is drawn from the COMPS database. The regressors with reported coefficients are the
average annual loss due to earthquake risk (obtained from AIR), indicators for whether an insurance firm (insurer or
insurance broker) purchased the property, for whether a broker arranged the transaction and for whether the buyer was a
broker, the log of the sale price, an indicator for corporate buyers, the 1990 property and personal crime risks (obtained
from CAP Index), the age of the property, the log of buyer and seller distances from the property, an indicator for
development projects and interactions between the average annual loss due to earthquake risk and the following variables:
insurance firm purchaser, property age, the fraction of the property’s census tract population that is African-American
(obtained from the 2000 census), the log of median home value in the prop erty’s census tract (obtained from the 2000
census) and an indicator for development projects. All regressions include fixed effects for property type, year and census
tract, with coefficients unreported for brevity. The regressions are estimated via binary logistic regression (Logit) with
t-statistics reported in parentheses. Reported R
2
for Logit specifications is McFadden’s pseudo R
2
.
50
Table V:
Earthquake Risk and Selection of Buyers and Banks
Dep endent variable Log of Median Home Value % Deposits Log of
in Buyer’s Zip Code in county bank assets
Sample Non-corporate Bank deposits Bank assets
buyers available available
N 17,967 7,487 11,478
Quake Risk 0.4346 0.4360 0.6033
(2.06) (1.65) (0.34)
Brokered 0.0322 -0.0218 0.0777
(4.15) (-1.74) (1.22)
Broker Buyer 0.0047 0.0038 -0.1009
(0.23) (0.14) (-0.61)
Log (Price) 0.0292 -0.0010 0.4168
(5.36) (-0.05) (3.30)
Corporate Buyer -0.0063 -0.0168
(-0.47) (-0.23)
Property Crime 0.0000 0.0000 -0.0004
(-0.10) (-0.12) (-0.25)
Personal Crime -0.0001 0.0001 -0.0008
(-0.40) (0.66) (-0.67)
Age 0.0000 0.0000 -0.0004
(0.16) (0.11) (-0.35)
Log (Buyer Distance) 0.0813 -0.0045 0.0175
(28.26) (-1.55) (1.06)
Log (Seller Distance) 0.0017 -0.0055 0.0016
(0.93) (-2.27) (0.12)
Development -0.0334 -0.0051 -0.3017
(-1.56) (-0.15) (-2.01)
Log(Loan Size) -0.0265 -0.0488
(-1.28) (-0.40)
Fixed effects?
Census tract Yes Yes Yes
Year Yes Yes Yes
Property type Yes Yes Yes
R
2
0.47 0.47 0.37
Results from the regressions of the median home value in the buyer’s zip code (from the 2000
census), the ratio of in-county deposits to total deposits for the bank extending the loan and the
log of the total assets of the bank extending the loan on quake risk and property and transaction
attributes. The regressors with reported coefficients are the average annual loss due to earthquake
risk (obtained from AIR), indicators for whether a broker arranged the transaction and for whether
the buyer was a broker, the log of the sale price (excluded from the cap rate and sale price regres-
sions), an indicator for corporate buyers, the 1990 property and personal crime risks (obtained
from CAP Index), the age of the property, the log of buyer and seller distances from the property
and an indicator for development projects. In the second and third columns, the log of loan size is
included as an additional control. All regressions include fixed effects for property type, year and
census tract, with coefficients not reported for brevity. All regressions are estimated via ordinary
least squares (OLS) with robust t-statistics rep orted in parentheses.
51
Table VI:
Earthquake Risk and Commercial Real Estate Prices
Dep endent variable Cap Log of Log of
rate price price
N 12,444 12,444 12,444
Quake Risk 1.2609 -0.1342 5.3954
(0.86) (-1.00) (12.96)
Log (Earnings) 0.9255 0.9503
(286.92) (273.58)
(Quake Risk) * Log (Earnings) -0.3468
(-14.12)
(Quake Risk) * Age -0.0035
(-3.13)
Brokered 0.3786 -0.0366 -0.0336
(5.71) (-5.91) (-5.52)
Broker Buyer 0.1068 -0.0079 -0.0073
(0.80) (-0.61) (-0.58)
Corporate Buyer 0.2281 0.0255 0.0270
(3.27) (3.85) (4.12)
Property Crime -0.0023 0.0002 0.0002
(-1.62) (1.50) (1.33)
Personal Crime 0.0037 -0.0004 -0.0004
(2.84) (-3.27) (-3.14)
Age 0.0053 -0.0011 -0.0009
(3.21) (-7.13) (-4.68)
Log (Buyer Distance) 0.0424 0.0035 0.0025
(3.42) (2.82) (2.05)
Log (Seller Distance) 0.0430 -0.0016 -0.0019
(3.59) (-1.37) (-1.67)
Development 0.0938 0.0098 0.0090
(0.55) (0.60) (0.56)
Fixed effects?
Census tract Yes Yes Yes
Year Yes Yes Yes
Property type Yes Yes Yes
R
2
0.43 0.97 0.98
Results from the regressions of capitalization rate (current earnings divided by sale price) and
log of sale price on quake risk and property and transaction attributes. The regressors with
reported coefficients are the average annual loss due to earthquake risk (obtained from AIR), the
log earnings (second and third columns), indicators for whether a broker arranged the transaction
and for whether the buyer was a broker, an indicator for corporate buyers, the 1990 property and
personal crime risks (obtained from CAP Index), the age of the property, the log of buyer and
seller distances from the prop erty, an indicator for development projects and interactions between
earthquake risk and the following variables: log of earnings and property age. In the fourth and
fifth columns, the log of loan size is included as an additional control. All regressions include
fixed effects for property type, year and census tract, with coefficients not reported for brevity.
All regressions are estimated via ordinary least squares (OLS) with robust t-statistics reported in
parentheses.
52
Table VII:
The Effect of the Northridge Earthquake on
Commercial Real Estate Prices and Financing
Dep endent variable Cap Loan Log of % Deposits
rate provided? bank assets in county
Sample All All L.A. County L.A. County
N 12,444 32,618 3,989 3,596
Quake Risk 1.5618 -2.7836 0.2840 0.3651
(1.08) (-2.96) (0.16) (1.38)
(Quake Risk) * Log (1+Days Post-quake) 0.1889 0.5732 0.1896 0.1204
(0.58) (2.57) (0.38) (1.77)
(Quake Risk) * (Year Post-quake) -1.7086 -2.5987 0.3925 -0.4682
(-1.03) (-2.31) (0.17) (-1.53)
Log (1+Days Post-quake) 0.0205 0.0000 -0.1043 -0.0230
(0.57) (0.00) (-1.09) (-1.86)
PGA 0.0314 0.0114 -0.0304 0.0033
(1.54) (0.87) (-1.22) (0.88)
Log (Price) -0.0090 0.8729 0.0460
(-0.58) (3.97) (1.33)
Brokered 0.3767 0.5625 -0.0556 -0.0220
(5.67) (18.63) (-0.48) (-1.33)
Broker Buyer 0.1097 0.1501 -0.1380 0.0249
(0.82) (1.74) (-0.54) (0.87)
Corporate Buyer 0.2268 -0.1885 0.0178 0.0271
(3.25) (-5.61) (0.13) (1.43)
Property Crime -0.0024 -0.0002 0.0010 0.0000
(-1.64) (-0.24) (0.40) (-0.06)
Personal Crime 0.0037 -0.0003 -0.0019 0.0001
(2.88) (-0.45) (-0.79) (0.19)
Log (Buyer Distance) 0.0423 -0.0909 -0.0160 0.0058
(3.42) (-12.70) (-0.54) (1.43)
Log (Seller Distance) 0.0433 -0.0004 0.0225 -0.0071
(3.62) (-0.06) (0.98) (-2.20)
Development 0.0938 0.0533 -0.3497 -0.0591
(0.55) (0.79) (-1.05) (-1.08)
Age 0.0053 -0.0017 0.0001 0.0003
(3.21) (-2.95) (0.06) (0.87)
Log (Loan Size) -0.4557 -0.0699
(-2.20) (-2.09)
Fixed effects?
Census tract Yes Yes Yes Yes
Property type Yes Yes Yes Yes
Year Fixed Effects? Yes Yes Yes Yes
Estimation method OLS Logit OLS OLS
R
2
0.43 0.19 0.37 0.35
Results from the regressions of capitalization (current earnings divided by sale price) rate, an indicator for whether a loan was
provided, the log of the total assets of the bank extending the loan and the ratio of in-county deposits to total deposits for
the bank extending the loan on quake risk, local shaking from the Northridge (1994) earthquake and property and transaction
attributes. The data is drawn from the COMPS database. The regressors with reported coefficients are the average annual
loss due to earthquake risk (obtained from AIR), the interaction of earthquake risk with the log of one plus the number of
days following the Northridge quake on which the transaction took place (for transactions within one year of the quake), the
interaction of earthquake risk with a dummy for the year following the Northridge quake, the log of one plus the number
of days following the Northridge quake on which the transaction took place, the peak ground acceleration (PGA), a shaking
intensity measure, of the Northridge earthquake at the property’s location (provided by the USGS), the log of the sale price
(excluded from the cap rate regression), indicators for whether a broker arranged the transaction and for whether the buyer
was a broker, an indicator for corporate buyers, the 1990 property and personal crime risks (obtained from CAP Index), the
age of the property, the log of buyer and seller distances from the property, an indicator for development projects, and, in
the third and fourth columns, the log of loan amount. All regressions include fixed effects for property type, year and census
tract, with coefficients not reported for brevity. The regressions are estimated via binary logistic regression (Logit) or ordinary
least squares (OLS), as described, with robust t-statistics reported in parentheses. Rep orted R
2
for Logit specifications is
McFadden’s pseudo R
2
.
53
Table VII I:
The Effect of the Northridge Earthquake on
Transaction Volumes for Properties
with Varying Quake Risks
Dep endent variable Quake risk Quake risk Quake risk
Sample All Bank Loans No Bank Loans
N 32,618 17,141 15,451
Log (1+Days Post-quake) 0.0003 0.0008 0.0000
(1.93) (2.61) (0.11)
PGA 0.0002 0.0002 0.0006
(0.78) (0.60) (1.07)
Log (Price) 0.0000 0.0000 -0.0001
(-0.20) (-0.10) (-0.64)
Brokered 0.0000 0.0003 -0.0003
(-0.13) (1.01) (-0.94)
Broker Buyer 0.0000 0.0004 -0.0001
(0.04) (0.51) (-0.12)
Corporate Buyer 0.0000 0.0000 -0.0002
(-0.10) (-0.05) (-0.88)
Property Crime 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000
(0.71) (-0.44) (0.82)
Personal Crime 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000
(-0.73) (0.32) (-0.79)
Log (Buyer Distance) 0.0000 0.0000 0.0001
(0.43) (-0.45) (1.26)
Log (Seller Distance) 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000
(-0.22) (-0.25) (0.54)
Development -0.0002 -0.0006 0.0006
(-0.45) (-1.33) (1.38)
Age 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000
(-0.48) (-1.11) (-0.40)
Fixed effects?
Census tract Yes Yes Yes
Year Yes Yes Yes
Property type Yes Yes Yes
Estimation method OLS OLS OLS
R
2
0.99 0.99 0.99
Results from the regressions of the average annual loss due to earthquake risk on the log
of one plus the number of days following the Northridge quake on which the transaction
took place (for transactions within one year of the quake), local shaking from the North-
ridge earthquake, the log of the sale price, indicators for whether a broker arranged the
transaction and for whether the buyer was a broker, an indicator for corporate buyers,
the 1990 property and personal crime risks (obtained from CAP Index), the age of the
property, the log of buyer and seller distances from the property, an indicator for devel-
opment projects and property age. The data is drawn from the AIR, COMPS and USGS
databases. All regressions include fixed effects for property type, year and census tract,
with coefficients not reported for brevity. The regressions are estimated via ordinary
least squares (OLS), with robust t-statistics rep orted in parentheses.
54
Table IX:
Hurricane Risk and Commercial Real Estate Financing
Dep endent variable Bank loan provided? Bank loan provided? Bank loan provided?
N 32,618 32,618 32,618
Hurricane Risk -0.0029 -0.0043 0.0048
(-1.09) (-2.26) (1.25)
(Hurricane Risk)*(Cat. Ins. Price Index) -0.0001
(-2.73)
Log (Price) -0.0094 -0.0072 -0.0063
(-0.61) (-0.51) (-0.44)
Brokered 0.5620 0.5389 0.5405
(18.62) (19.37) (19.42)
Broker Buyer 0.1525 0.2381 0.2445
(1.76) (2.91) (2.99)
Corporate Buyer -0.1874 -0.1990 -0.1990
(-5.58) (-6.43) (-6.43)
Property Crime -0.0002 -0.0006 -0.0006
(-0.32) (-1.83) (-1.87)
Personal Crime -0.0002 0.0001 0.0001
(-0.39) (0.21) (0.25)
Log (Buyer Distance) -0.0909 -0.0848 -0.0850
(-12.70) (-12.74) (-12.76)
Log (Seller Distance) -0.0001 -0.0005 -0.0005
(-0.01) (-0.08) (-0.08)
Development 0.0540 -0.0027 -0.0032
(0.80) (-0.04) (-0.05)
Age -0.0017 -0.0020 -0.0020
(-2.94) (-3.76) (-3.72)
Fixed effects?
Geographical Tract Zip Code Zip Code
Year Yes Yes Yes
Property type Yes Yes Yes
Estimation method Logit Logit Logit
R
2
0.19 0.17 0.17
Results from the regressions of an indicator for whether a bank loan was provided on hurricane risk and
property and transaction attributes. The data is drawn from the COMPS database. The regressors with
reported coefficients are the property’s percentile hurricane risk within its county (obtained from AIR), an
interaction of this hurricane risk with Guy Carpenter’s Catastrophe Insurance Price Index (obtained from
Guy Carp enter), the log of the sale price, indicators for whether a broker arranged the transaction and for
whether the buyer was a broker or a corporation, the 1990 property and personal crime risks (obtained from
CAP Index), the log of buyer and seller distances from the property, an indicator for development projects
and the age of the prop erty. All regressions include fixed effects for property type, year and census tract,
with coefficients unrep orted for brevity. The regressions are estimated via binary logistic regression (Logit)
with t-statistics reported in parentheses. Reported R
2
is McFadden’s pseudo R
2
.
55