1097
DRIVE AT YOUR OWN RISK: UBER
VIOLATES UNFAIR COMPETITION LAW S
BY MISLEADING UBERX DRIVERS ABOUT
THEIR INSURANCE COVERAGE
Abstract: Ride-sharing services such as Uber and Lyft have revolutionized the
private transportation market. Given the lack of clear regulations over these busi-
nesses, however, insurance industry experts disagree with Uber about the ade-
quacy of uberX drivers’ existing insurance coverage. This Note asserts that Uber
misleads uberX drivers about the type and amount of coverage available to them,
as uberX drivers have no first-party protections in place while they drive around
searching for fares. This Note further argues that based on these insurance mis-
representations, Uber may be liable to injured uberX drivers under California’s
unfair competition law for engaging in unfair business practices. Accordingly,
uberX drivers should be entitled to restitution for their injuries and injunctive re-
lief to prevent Uber from continuing to mislead uberX drivers about their insur-
ance coverage.
INTRODUCTION
On New Year’s Eve of 2013, around eight o’clock at night, six-year-old So-
fia Liu was walking in downtown San Francisco with her mother and four-year-
old brother.
1
As the family crossed a street in a crosswalk, a Honda sport utility
vehicle taking a right-hand turn failed to yield to the pedestrians and struck the
Liu family.
2
Sofia’s brother and mother survived the accident, but Sofia did not.
3
As it turned out, the driver of the Honda was an uberX driver.
4
Although the ub-
erX driver did not have a passenger at the time, he was logged into the Uber
Technologies, Inc. (“Uber”) mobile phone application (“app”) and searching for
fares.
5
Thus, when Sofia’s parents sued the driver for wrongful death, Uber de-
1
Family of Girl Killed in SF Crosswalk Suing Uber for Wrongful Death, CBS SF BAY AREA
(Jan. 27, 2014, 4:13 PM), http://sanfrancisco.cbslocal.com/2014/01/27/family-of-girl-killed-in-sf-
crosswalk-suing-uber-for-wrongful-death/, archived at http://perma.cc/G3XE-5TJK; Henry K. Lee,
Former Uber Driver Charged in Girl’s Crosswalk Death in S.F., SFG
ATE (Dec. 9, 2014, 5:37 PM),
http://www.sfgate.com/crime/article/Former-Uber-driver-charged-in-girl-s-crosswalk-5944049.php,
archived at http://perma.cc/9TML-UZ58.
2
Lee, supra note 1.
3
Id. (noting that in December of 2014, the uberX driver was charged with vehicular manslaughter
for Sofia’s death).
4
Family of Girl Killed in SF Crosswalk Suing Uber for Wrongful Death, supra note 1.
5
Id.; Doug Sovern, Parents of San Francisco Girl Fatally Struck by Uber Driver Seek Stricter
Ridesharing Rules, CBS
SF BAY AREA (June 25, 2014, 4:01 PM), http://sanfrancisco.cbslocal.com/
2014/06/25/uber-and-other-app-ride-services-urged-to-carry-commercial-insurance-before-state-senate/,
1098 Boston College Law Review [Vol. 56:1097
nied that its commercial auto insurance policy covered the drivers liability in
between fares.
6
As ride-sharing becomes more and more common, so do ride-sharing ac-
cidents and subsequent insurance coverage disputes.
7
Despite Ubers represen-
tations that uberX drivers are adequately insured, some insurance industry ex-
perts believe that uberX drivers still face coverage gaps while they drive
around searching for fares.
8
Indeed some uberX drivers involved in accidents
archived at http://perma.cc/4UY4-FLCB (reporting that Sofia’s mother alleges that she saw the uberX
driver using his phone). But see Lee, supra note 1 (reporting that Uber maintains that the uberX driver
was not responding to a ride request in the app at the time of the accident).
6
Carolyn Said, Hybrid Insurance for Uber, Lyft Drivers Is on the Way, SF GATE (Nov. 14, 2014,
5:17 PM), http://www.sfgate.com/business/article/Hybrid-insurance-for-Uber-Lyft-drivers-is-on-the-
5894075.php, archived at http://perma.cc/9UQB-WVGR; Sovern, supra note 5. Since Sofia’s death in
December 2013, Uber has begun providing a contingent liability policy to cover uberX drivers when
the driver has the app on but does not yet have a passenger. See Nairi Hourdajian, Eliminating Rides-
haring Ambiguity, U
BER (Mar. 14, 2014), http://blog.uber.com/uberXridesharinginsurance, archived
at http://perma.cc/LTS4-AWQR [hereinafter Hourdajian, Eliminating Ridesharing Ambiguity] (an-
nouncing Uber’s new contingent liability coverage in the wake of the San Francisco tragedy). Prob-
lems with this solution are explored below. See infra notes 4668 and accompanying text (explaining
Uber’s insurance for ride-sharing drivers).
7
See Brad Aaron, TLC: Driver Who Killed Man on UES Works for Uber [Updated],
S
TREETSBLOG (Jan. 5, 2015), http://www.streetsblog.org/2015/01/05/tlc-unlicensed-driver-who-
killed-man-on-ues-works-for-uber/, archived at http://perma.cc/5H8S-7HHX (reporting on a state-
ment Uber issued after an Uber driver killed a man in New York City in January 2015, which pointed
out that the Uber driver had a commercial insurance policy associated with his taxicab license); Emily
Badger, The Strange Tale of an Uber Car Crash and What It Means for the Future of Auto Insurance,
C
ITYLAB (Sept. 10, 2013), http://www.citylab.com/commute/2013/09/real-future-ride-sharing-may-
all-come-down-insurance/6832/, archived at http://perma.cc/B7M6-7D3C [hereinafter Badger,
Strange Tale] (noting that Uber argued that its auto insurance did not cover an Uber driver who in-
jured two people in a March 2013 accident because the driver did not have a customer at the time);
Vauhini Vara, Uber, Lyft, and Liability, N
EW YORKER (Nov. 4, 2014), http://www.newyorker.com/
business/currency/uber-lyft-liability, archived at http://perma.cc/J5EE-62P8 (explaining that in the
wrongful death lawsuit over Sofia’s death, Uber denied that its liability policy covered the driver
because he did not have a passenger at the time); Randy Wallace, Accident Leaves Houston Uber
Driver with Regrets, M
Y FOX HOUSTON (Jan. 4, 2015, 10:30 PM), http://www.myfoxhouston.com/
story/27656550/accident-leaves-houston-uber-driver-with-regrets, archived at http://perma.cc/8KDM-
7XS6 (reporting that a Houston uberX driver who caused a collision was unable to get compensation
for his own injuries through Uber’s insurance); see also Said, supra note 6 (noting the vast potential
for insurance coverage disputes, given that ride-sharing drivers’ insurance coverage varies over time).
8
See Sharing a Ride, but Not Insurance: Ridesharing Drivers May Face Insurance Coverage
Gap, N
ATL ASSN OF INS. COMMRS (Aug. 2014), http://www.naic.org/documents/consumer_
alert_ridesharing_drivers.htm, archived at http://perma.cc/65ZH-W325 [hereinafter NAIC Consumer
Alert for Ridesharing Drivers] (warning ride-sharing drivers about their potential gaps in insurance
and the various livery exclusions contained in many personal policies); Notice to Transportation Net-
work Company Drivers, C
AL. DEPT OF INS., http://www.insurance.ca.gov/0250-insurers/0300-insurers/
0200-bulletins/bulletin-notices-commiss-opinion/TransNetwkDrvrs.cfm, archived at http://perma.
cc/25ZU-TSWQ (last visited May 17, 2015) (warning ride-sharing drivers that transportation network
companies (“TNCs”) do not provide medical payments, comprehensive, collision, or uninsured/
underinsured motorist (“UM/UIM”) insurance coverages). But see Hourdajian, Eliminating Rideshar-
ing Ambiguity, supra note 6 (stating that “drivers who use our app . .
. should have the confidence that
any potential ‘insurance gap’ is covered with a safety net”); Nairi Hourdajian, Insurance for uberX
2015] Uber’s Insurance Coverage and Unfair Competition Laws 1099
have unexpectedly found themselves without the benefit of Ubers auto insur-
ance.
9
Just as with the uberX driver who killed Sofia Liu, Uber denied that its
insurance policy covered a Houston uberX drivers medical bills and vehicle
repairs after he got into an accident while transporting passengers in December
of 2014.
10
Based on the discrepancy between Ubers claims about uberX drivers’ in-
surance coverage and the actual coverage drivers receive, injured uberX driv-
ers may be able to sue Uber in California for engaging in unfair business prac-
tices.
11
Violations of California’s unfair competition law (“UCL”) could ex-
with Ridesharing, UBER (Mar. 19, 2015), http://blog.uber.com/ridesharinginsurance, archived at
http://perma.cc/YL28-XH3M [hereinafter Hourdajian, Insurance for uberX] (stating that the limits of
Uber’s contingent liability policy, which covers uberX drivers between trips, “meets or exceeds the
requirements for [third] party liability insurance in every state”). See generally N
ATL ASSN OF INS.
COMMRS, TRANSPORTATION NETWORK COMPANY INSURANCE PRINCIPLES FOR LEGISLATORS AND
REGULATORS (2015), available at http://www.naic.org/documents/committees_c_sharing_econ_wg_
exposure_adopted_tnc_white_paper_150331.pdf?1430061828513, archived at http://perma.cc/33Z3-
M9TB [hereinafter NAIC
WHITE PAPER ON TNC INSURANCE] (examining the insurance coverage
issues that plague ride-sharing drivers and proposing legislative solutions).
9
See Vara, supra note 7 (stating that Uber denied that its commercial liability policy covered the
driver responsible for killing the six-year-old girl in San Francisco); Wallace, supra note 7 (reporting
that Uber’s liability policy did not cover a Houston uberX driver’s personal medical bills or vehicle
damage).
10
See Catherine L. Rassman, Regulating Rideshare Without Stifling Innovation: Examining the
Drivers, the Insurance “Gap,” and Why Pennsylvania Should Get on Board, 15 P
ITT. J. TECH. L. &
POLY 81, 89 (2014) (explaining how Uber denied insurance coverage for the uberX driver when
Sofia’s parents sued Uber); Wallace, supra note 7 (reporting that Uber refused insurance coverage for
a Houston driver’s injuries). Note that liability and coverage are two separate legal issues in an insur-
ance dispute. See Jordan v. Consol. Mut. Ins. Co., 130 Cal. Rptr. 446, 44849 (Cal. Ct. App. 1976)
(distinguishing between liability and coverage issues where judgment was entered against deceased
driver for causing car accident and injured plaintiff argued that vehicle owner’s insurance policy
should pay the judgment). Liability refers to the determination of fault in the accident. See id. at 448
(noting that the decedent, a Gulf Station employee, was liable for causing the plaintiff $55,000 in
damages while driving a customer’s Corvette). Coverage, on the other hand, refers to the amount and
type of insurance proceeds to which an injured party has access. See id. at 452, 456 (finding that the
Corvette owner’s insurance policy covered anyone with permission to drive the vehicle). This Note is
concerned with coverage (i.e., an uberX driver’s access to insurance proceeds) rather than who is
liable when an uberX driver gets into an accident. See infra notes 4668 and accompanying text (ex-
plaining uberX drivers’ access to insurance policies).
11
See CAL. BUS. & PROF. CODE §§ 17200, 17203 (West 2012) (stating that “[a]ny person who
engages, has engaged, or proposed to engage in unfair competition may be enjoined,” and defining
unfair competition as “any unlawful, unfair or fraudulent business act or practice and unfair, decep-
tive, untrue or misleading advertising and any act prohibited by [California false advertising laws]”);
Dan Packel, Lyft, Uber Ridesharing Bids Fall Short, Pa. Insurers Say, L
AW360 (Sept. 16, 2014, 3:53
PM), http://www.law360.com/articles/577690/lyft-uber-ridesharing-bids-fall-short-pa-insurers-say,
archived at http://perma.cc/T8FJ-926M[hereinafter Packel, Lyft, Uber Ridesharing Bids] (noting the
Insurance Federation of Pennsylvania’s opinion that Uber lacks adequate insurance and insurance
education for uberX drivers). This Note examines California law because Uber’s and Lyft’s driver
agreements contain a choice of law provision stating that California law governs the agreements. See
O’Connor v. Uber Tech., Inc., No. C133826, 2014 WL 4382880, at *1 (N.D. Cal. Sept. 4, 2014)
(providing the language of the California choice of law provision in Uber’s driver licensing agree-
1100 Boston College Law Review [Vol. 56:1097
pose Uber and other transportation network companies (“TNCs”) to ride-
sharing drivers’ claims for restitution and injunctive relief, as well as negative
publicity.
12
Accordingly, it is in the best interests of TNCs and ride-sharing
drivers to heed the numerous warnings from insurance industry insiders about
drivers’ insurance gaps.
13
This Note argues that Uber’s misrepresentations to uberX drivers should
be found to violate California’s UCL, as they constitute an unfair business
practice.
14
Part I discusses how ride-sharing apps function and Ubers insur-
ment); Cotter v. Lyft, Inc., 13cv04065, 2014 WL 3884416, at *4 (N.D. Cal. Aug. 7, 2014) (stating
that Lyft’s driver contracts contain a California choice of law provision). This Note does not examine
the enforceability of these choice of law provisions, nor does it address whether California has per-
sonal jurisdiction over out-of-state plaintiffs. Cf. Ehret v. Uber Tech., Inc., No. C140113, 2014 WL
4640170, at *1, *45 (N.D. Cal. Sept. 17, 2014) (allowing an out-of-state consumer’s UCL claims
against Uber to proceed); O’Connor, 2014 WL 4382880, at *1112 (upholding Uber’s contractual
choice of law provision but refusing to apply California law extraterritorially and dismissing out-of
state Uber drivers’ UCL claims).
12
See CAL. BUS. & PROF. CODE §§ 1720317204 (providing that “[a]ny person who engages . . .
in unfair competition may be enjoined,” and that actions for injunctions may be brought “by a person
who has suffered injury in fact and has lost money or property as a result”); Cel-Tech Commc’n, Inc.
v. L.A. Cellular Tel. Co., 973 P.2d 527, 539 (Cal. 1999) (stating that plaintiffs can obtain restitution as
well); see Serena Saitto, Inside Big Taxi’s Dirty War with Uber, B
LOOMBERG BUS. (Mar. 11, 2015,
8:00 AM), http://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2015-03-11/inside-big-taxi-s-dirty-war-with-
uber, archived at http://perma.cc/4TR4-63HU (reporting that taxi associations have hired people to
dig up dirt on Uber); Vara, supra note 7 (reporting that the statement Uber posted to its website fol-
lowing Sofia’s death seemed callous in comparison to Lyft Inc. (“Lyft”)’s handling of a similar inci-
dent). This Note examines California’s UCL case law because it may provide guidance to other states
in interpreting their similar unfair competition statutes. See Federal Trade Commission Act, 15 U.S.C.
§ 45(a)(1) (2012) (stating that “unfair methods of competition in or affecting commerce, and unfair or
deceptive acts or practices in or affecting commerce, are hereby declared unlawful”); Neil A. Helf-
man, Proof of Statutory Unfair Business Practices, 36 A
M. JUR. PROOF OF FACTS 3D 221, 22930
(1996) (updated Apr. 2015) (describing how many states, including California, followed the Federal
Trade Commission Act (“FTCA)’s lead and enacted similar statutes prohibiting unfair competition).
13
See, e.g., Eric Nordman, Ride-Sharing: New Technology Creates Insurance Challenges, CIPR
Newsletter (Nat’l Ass’n of Ins. Comm’rs & Ctr. for Ins. Pol’y & Research, Kansas City, Mo.), July,
2014, at 78, available at http://www.naic.org/documents/cipr_events_140819_rideshare_newsletter.
pdf, archived at http://perma.cc/26R4-A83U (pointing out gaps in ride-sharing drivers’ insurance that
arise from the fact that drivers’ personal auto policies will not cover commercial activity); Commer-
cial Ride-Sharing, N
ATL ASSN OF INS. COMMRS, http://www.naic.org/cipr_topics/topic_commercial_
ride_sharing.htm, archived at http://perma.cc/3QGF-FPTY (last updated Oct. 24, 2014) (stating that
approximately twenty-five states have issued bulletins warning consumers about potential gaps and
limitations of ride-sharing insurance coverage); NAIC Consumer Alert for Ridesharing Drivers, supra
note 8 (warning ride-sharing drivers that they may face a gap in coverage between their personal poli-
cies and TNCs’ commercial policies); Notice to Transportation Network Company Drivers, supra
note 8 (advising ride-sharing drivers to purchase “a commercial policy with medical payments, com-
prehensive, collision and UM/UIM” to fill the gaps in their insurance coverage); Sharing a Ride, but
Not Insurance: Protect Yourself as a Ridesharing Passenger, N
ATL ASSN OF INS. COMMRS (Aug.
2014), http://www.naic.org/documents/consumer_alert_ridesharing_passengers.htm, archived at http://
perma.cc/R9SZ-5WLW [hereinafter NAIC Consumer Alert for Ridesharing Passengers] (warning
ride-sharing customers that TNCs and ride-sharing vehicles are not subject to the same licensing and
insurance requirements as taxis and limos).
14
See infra notes 188243 and accompanying text.
2015] Uber’s Insurance Coverage and Unfair Competition Laws 1101
ance structure for uberX drivers.
15
Part II introduces California’s UCL and ex-
amines the different tests for unfairness that courts use to determine whether a
given business practice violates the UCL.
16
Finally, Part III argues that courts
should find Ubers misrepresentations about the availability of insurance cov-
erage for uberX drivers to be unfair in violation of the UCL, thereby entitling
injured uberX drivers to restitution and injunctive relief.
17
I.
THERES AN APP FOR THAT: UBERS RISE AND EXISTING INSURANCE
COVERAGE FOR UBERX DRIVERS
With the rising popularity of ride-sharing, there is an increasing need to
regulate the insurance coverage of ride-sharing drivers.
18
This Part examines
Ubers rapid expansion into the transportation market and existing insurance
coverage for uberX drivers.
19
Section A provides a brief background on Uber
and its dominance in the ride-sharing market.
20
Section B then explores how
Uber drivers, particularly uberX drivers, are insured.
21
Finally, Section C dis-
cusses recent attempts to regulate TNCs that could impact how Uber and other
ride-sharing companies structure their insurance.
22
A. Giving Them a Run for Their Money: The Emergence of Ride-Sharing
Shakes Up the Transportation Industry
As the sharing economy expands, ride-sharing has become a popular and
commercially viable peer-to-peer service.
23
Ride-sharing is a transportation
service whereby people without commercial licenses use their own personal
15
See infra notes 1883 and accompanying text.
16
See infra notes 84179 and accompanying text.
17
See infra notes 180243 and accompanying text.
18
See Nordman, supra note 13, at 68 (discussing the emergence of ride-sharing facilitated
though TNCs and the California Insurance Commissioner’s recommendations for regulating ride-
sharing insurance to protect drivers and passengers); NAIC Consumer Alert for Ridesharing Passen-
gers, supra note 13 (assuring consumers that state insurance regulators and legislators are starting to
regulate TNCs). This Note uses the terms “regulation” and “law” interchangeably to refer to any legal
rule governing the public’s behavior. See infra notes 18243 and accompanying text (employing these
terms).
19
See infra notes 1883 and accompanying text.
20
See infra notes 2345 and accompanying text.
21
See infra notes 4668 and accompanying text.
22
See infra notes 6983 and accompanying text.
23
See CHRISTOPHER KOOPMAN ET AL., MERCATUS CENTER, THE SHARING ECONOMY AND
CONSUMER PROTECTION REGULATION: THE CASE FOR POLICY CHANGE 3–5 (Dec. 2014), available
at http://mercatus.org/sites/default/files/Koopman-Sharing-Economy.pdf, archived at http://perma.cc/
V3KN-BAB9 (discussing the rapid growth and value of the sharing economy, loosely defined as an
internet marketplace where individuals come together to exchange underutilized goods or services).
Well-known sharing economy companies include Airbnb, Uber, Lyft, and TaskRabbit. Molly Cohen
& Corey Zehngebot, What’s Old Becomes New: Regulating the Sharing Economy, 58 B
OS. B.J., Spring
2014, at 6, 6.
1102 Boston College Law Review [Vol. 56:1097
vehicles to provide rides to strangers for a fee.
24
Ride-sharing drivers provide
customers with door-to-door service to their destinations, just like a taxicab,
but the transaction tends to be cheaper and more convenient for the customer.
25
As a result, ride-sharing has introduced competition into the taxicab market.
26
24
John G. Browning, Emerging Technology and Its Impact on Automotive Litigation, 81 DEF.
COUNS. J. 83, 84 (2014); Ken Yeung, Class-Action Lawsuit Filed Against Uber by San Francisco
Taxi Drivers for Unfair Competition, T
HE NEXT WEB (Nov. 14, 2012, 5:59 PM), http://thenextweb.
com/insider/2012/11/14/class-action-lawsuit-filed-against-uber-by-san-francisco-taxicab-drivers-citing-
unfair-business-competition/, archived at http://perma.cc/D2LU-L64C (describing California cab driv-
ers’ class action lawsuit alleging that uberX operates as an illegal taxicab and limousine service). Ride-
sharing providers are not subject to the same local licensing and insurance requirements that apply to
taxicabs and limousines. NAIC Consumer Alert for Ridesharing Passengers, supra note 13; see Bos-
ton Cab Dispatch, Inc. v. Uber Techs., Inc., No. 13-10769-NMG, 2014 WL 1338148, at *13 (D.
Mass. Mar. 27, 2014) (explaining how Boston taxicabs are regulated by Boston Police Department
Rule 403 and that Uber vehicles do not fall within the scope of Rule 403). See generally B
OS. POLICE
DEPT, RULE 403, HACKNEY CARRIAGE RULES AND REGULATIONS (Aug. 29, 2008), available at
https://static1.squarespace.com/static/5086f19ce4b0ad16ff15598d/t/52af61e1e4b0871946c07a41/
1387225569980/Rule+403.pdf, archived at http://perma.cc/JTN7-6B3P (prescribing the Boston Police
Commissioner’s taxicab and radio association regulations); Thomson Reuters, Licensing of Taxi Driv-
ers, 0140 REGSURVEYS 2 (June 2014) (providing a fifty-state survey of state regulations for li-
censed taxicab drivers). Car-sharing is also distinguishable from ride-sharing in that car-sharing in-
volves a company or individual renting cars out to drivers, as rental car companies do. See Browning,
supra, at 8485 (pointing out the similarity between car- and ride-sharing and rental car companies);
Side by Side Comparison of Car Sharing and Ridesharing, N
ATL ASSN OF INS. COMMRS, http://
www.naic.org/documents/cipr_events_140819_sidebyside_rideshare_carshare.pdf, archived at http://
perma.cc/2U4X-M2VX (last visited May 17, 2015) (demonstrating how car-sharing and ride-sharing
differ); see also Z
IPCAR, http://www.zipcar.com, archived at http://perma.cc/8YPY-5KQ4 (last visited
May 17, 2015) (explaining that ZipCar is a car-sharing company that owns vehicles that members rent
to drive themselves around).
25
See NAIC Consumer Alert for Ridesharing Passengers, supra note 13 (comparing taxicabs to
uberX and noting that uberX is a cheaper but less safe alternative); Luke O’Neil, Hail, Boston: The
Uber vs Taxi Livery War Is Changing the Industry, B
OS. MAG. (Aug. 2014), http://www.boston
magazine.com/news/article/2014/07/30/uber-vs-taxis/, archived at http://perma.cc/XQ3J-UQBC (dis-
cussing Uber’s advantages over taxicabs, including the convenience of hailing a car from indoors).
But cf. Lori Aratani, Proposal Would Allow D.C. Cabs to Embrace ‘Surge Pricing, W
ASH. POST
(Apr. 7, 2014), http://www.washingtonpost.com/local/trafficandcommuting/proposal-would-allow-dc-
cabs-to-embrace-surge-pricing/2014/04/07/0bb48f28-be85-11e3-b195-dd0c1174052c_story.html,
archived at http://perma.cc/FD28-DBBT (explaining Uber’s practice of surge pricing, or raising prices
in response to increased demand).
26
See Josh Barro, Under Pressure from Uber, Taxi Medallion Prices Are Plummeting, N.Y.
TIMES (Nov. 27, 2014), http://www.nytimes.com/2014/11/28/upshot/under-pressure-from-uber-taxi-
medallion-prices-are-plummeting.html?_r=0&abt=0002&abg=1, archived at http://perma.cc/FD4J-
GUYR (describing how the prices of taxicab medallions are down in many cities due to competition
from Uber and Lyft); Commercial Ride-Sharing, supra note 13 (describing ride-shar
ing as a new
alternative to public transportation); London’s Anti-Uber Taxi Protest Brings Traffic to Standstill,
BBC
NEWS (June 11, 2014), http://www.bbc.com/news/uk-england-london-27799938, archived at
http://perma/cc/GW5M-8WDC (describing a London taxicab protest against Uber, which resulted in
an 850% increase in downloads of the Uber app); O’Neil, supra note 25 (pointing out that a few me-
dallion owners cornered the Boston taxicab market and drove up costs, until Uber began offering
customers other options).
2015] Uber’s Insurance Coverage and Unfair Competition Laws 1103
Furthermore, ride-sharing has the potential to reduce traffic, relieve the burden
on public transportation systems, and improve community relations.
27
Transportation network companies (“TNCs”) enable ride-sharing transac-
tions between drivers and customers.
28
TNCs do not own any vehicles; rather,
TNCs connect customers with nearby drivers through a mobile phone applica-
tion (“app”), much like a taxi dispatcher does.
29
To hail a ride-sharing driver,
customers download the TNC’s app, store their credit card information in the
app, and then request a ride from a driver in the area.
30
Any of the TNCs local
drivers logged into the app on their mobile phones can accept the ride re-
quest.
31
After the ride is complete, the TNC app charges the fare to the custom-
ers credit card automatically.
32
TNCs profit by taking a percentage of the fares
and leaving the remainder to the drivers.
33
27
See Accelerating the Lyft Movement, LYFT BLOG (Mar. 11, 2015), http://blog.lyft.com/posts/
2015/3/11/accelerating-the-lyft-movement, archived at http://perma.cc/KD4P-2LGS (stating Lyft’s
goal of fostering community); Commercial Ride-Sharing, supra note 13 (stating that TNCs can “less-
en traffic congestion, improve the environment, and enhance social connection”); Gregory Ferenstein,
Two New Studies Show Why Uber Makes Cities More Productive and Less Congested, V
ENTURE-
BEAT (Sept. 3, 2014, 2:12 PM), http://venturebeat.com/2014/09/03/two-new-studies-show-why-uber-
makes-cities-more-productive-and-less-congested/, archived at http://perma.cc/H3G7-B2RE (explain-
ing studies in San Francisco and New York City that found that ride-sharing reduced rider waiting
times and city congestion and could reduce traffic pollution). But see Melkorka Licea et al., More
Uber Cars Than Yellow Taxis on the Road in NYC, N.Y.
POST (Mar. 17, 2015, 11:43 PM), http://
nypost.com/2015/03/17/more-uber-cars-than-yellow-taxis-on-the-road-in-nyc/, archived at http://
perma.cc/7XQ5-2A3A (noting that with more Uber limousines in New York City than medallion-
bearing cabs, traffic congestion has increased along with competition).
28
See Nordman, supra note 13, at 6 (explaining how TNCs’ online platforms facilitate ride-
sharing by connecting riders with drivers through a mobile phone application). Other ride-sharing
TNCs include Lyft and Sidecar. See Browning, supra note 24, at 84.
29
See Boston Cab, 2014 WL 1338148, at *2 (explaining how the Uber app generates assignments
for Uber drivers, similar to the way in which taxicab radio associations provide dispatch services to
taxicab drivers); Browning, supra note 24, at 84 (comparing TNCs, which do not own any vehicles, to
taxi dispatchers because they connect drivers with nearby riders). Uber, Lyft and Sidecar all function
in the same way. Compare U
BER, https://www.uber.com, archived at http://perma.cc/4ETG-FZZY
(last visited May 17, 2015) (explaining that customers use the Uber app to hail a ride with an Uber
vehicle), with L
YFT, https://www.lyft.com, archived at http://perma.cc/J6G3-T6S5 (last visited May
17, 2015) (explaining that the Lyft app connects customers with ride-sharing drivers), and S
IDECAR,
https://www.side.cr, archived at http://perma.cc/UX8J-XDFD (last visited May 17, 2015) (explaining
how the Sidecar app similarly connects customers with ride-sharing drivers, except customers learn in
advance how much the fare will cost).
30
See Boston Cab, 2014 WL 1338148, at *2 (describing how Uber customers use the Uber app to
request a ride).
31
See id. (stating that taxicab drivers choose to make themselves available for hire through the
Uber app while also remaining available for dispatch by their radio associations); Browning, supra
note 24, at 84 (discussing how the Uber app uses cell phone GPS technology to connect customers
with nearby drivers).
32
See Boston Cab, 2014 WL 1338148, at *2 (stating that the Uber fare is charged to the custom-
er’s preauthorized credit card); Nordman, supra note 6, at 6 (stating that no tipping is involved in an
Uber transaction). The driver’s cell phone tracks the distance and duration of the ride, which are then
used to calculate the fare. See Mike DeBonis, Uber Runs Afoul of Massachusetts Regulators, W
ASH.
1104 Boston College Law Review [Vol. 56:1097
The worlds largest TNC is Uber.
34
Founded in San Francisco in 2009,
Uber currently operates in fifty-five countries and in over 260 cities world-
wide.
35
Hundreds of thousands of drivers use Uber’s platform to provide rides
to customers, and Uber continues to grow its fleet of drivers and expand its
services.
36
Among the various transportation options Uber offers, its most pop-
POST (Aug. 16, 2012), http://www.washingtonpost.com/blogs/mike-debonis/post/uber-runs-afoul-of-
massachusetts-regulators/2012/08/10/e8044bc6-e317-11e1-98e7-89d659f9c106_blog.html, archived
at http://perma.cc/9B4Z-NPFB (noting that Massachusetts regulators challenged but ultimately ap-
proved of Uber’s GPS metering system, and providing a link to the Massachusetts Division of Stand-
ards’ order).
33
See Ehret, 2014 WL 4640170, at *1 (challenging Uber’s practice of charging customers a
twenty percent fee on top of its metered fare, calling the fee a driver gratuity, and then keeping a “sub-
stantial” portion for itself); Boston Cab, 2014 WL 1338148, at *2 (alleging that Uber adds a twenty
percent “gratuity” for drivers to its fares but only remits half of the gratuity to drivers); Nordman,
supra note 13, at 6 (stating that TNCs take a percentage of drivers’ sales).
34
See Scott Austin et al., The Billion-Dollar Startup Club, WALL ST. J. (Feb. 28, 2015), http://
graphics.wsj.com/billion-dollar-club/, archived at http://perma.cc/PH3W-92RU (noting that Uber was
valued at over $41 billion in December of 2014, making it the second largest venture-backed private
company in the world); Michael Wolff, The Tech Company of the Year Is Uber, USA
TODAY (Dec.
22, 2013, 10:54 PM), http://www.usatoday.com/story/money/columnist/wolff/2013/12/22/the-success-
of-app-based-car-service-uber/4141669/, archived at http://perma.cc/44VG-D3B5 (stating that if Uber
meets its goal of earning $50 billion in revenue, it would become the world’s largest transportation
company). But see Scott Cendrowski, China Has a New Taxi App Monopolistand It Isn’t Uber,
F
ORTUNE (Feb. 16, 2015, 6:30 AM), http://fortune.com/2015/02/16/china-has-a-new-taxi-app-
monopolist-and-it-isnt-uber/, archived at http://perma.cc/3EKD-XGS7 (describing the battle among
taxi-hailing apps in China, where Uber is relatively new to the market). Uber’s closest competitor in
the United States, Lyft, was valued at $2.5 billion in March of 2015. See Austin, supra; Adam
Lashinsky, Uber Banks on World Domination, F
ORTUNE (Sept. 18, 2014, 7:25 AM), http://fortune.
com/2014/09/18/uber-banks-on-world-domination/, archived at http://perma.cc/5FP4-NR6D (refer-
ring to Lyft as Uber’s “pip-squeak rival”).
35
See Lashinsky, supra note 34 (describing Uber’s origins); Where Is Uber Currently Available?,
U
BER, https://www.uber.com/cities, archived at http://perma.cc/3HWP-BCF4 (last visited May 17,
2015) (listing cities where Uber operates). By comparison, Lyft operates in only sixty U.S. cities. See
Cities We’re In, L
YFT, https://www.lyft.com/cities, archived at http://perma.cc/TR56-XADM (last
visited May 17, 2015) (listing the cities in which Lyft operates).
36
See Emily Badger, Now We Know How Many Drivers Uber HasAnd Have a Better Idea of
What They’re Making, W
ASH. POST (Jan. 22, 2015), http://www.washingtonpost.com/blogs/wonk
blog/wp/2015/01/22/now-we-know-many-drivers-uber-has-and-how-much-money-theyre-making%
E2%80%8B/, archived at http://perma.cc/E66R-V84A [hereinafter Badger, Now We Know] (reporting
that Uber had over 162,000 active drivers in December 2014 and that its cadre of drivers has doubled
every six months over the past two years); Lashinsky supra note 34 (reporting that Uber claims to
have hundreds of thousands of drivers and describing Uber’s growth strategy). In addition to provid-
ing ground transportation, Uber has experimented with water transportation, food delivery, and heli-
copter rides. See Kate, Elevate Your Ride to Coachella Valley with UberCHOPPER, U
BER (Apr. 1,
2015), http://blog.uber.com/festivalchopperSD, archived at http://perma.cc/FD5S-KT75 (describing
Uber’s helicopter service); Maya Kosoff, Uber’s Seamless Killer Is Launching a Dinner Option in Los
Angeles, B
US. INSIDER (Dec. 8, 2014), http://www.businessinsider.com/ubers-seamless-killer-uberfresh-
is-launching-a-dinner-option-in-los-angeles-2014-12, archived at http://perma.cc/4RHC-4G4E (de-
scribing Uber’s food delivery service); Conor Myhrvold, Uber Boat Meets #Uberdata, U
BER (July 15,
2014), http://blog.uber.com/uberboatrecap, archived at http://perma.cc/7YND-RHXJ (describing
Uber’s boat service).
2015] Uber’s Insurance Coverage and Unfair Competition Laws 1105
ular service is uberX, the low cost ride-sharing option.
37
Uber continues to ac-
tively recruit uberX drivers to meet the demand for ride-sharing services.
38
Because Uber does not have to comply with local taxicab and limousine
regulations, it has pursued innovative but controversial business methods.
39
Regulators have challenged its practice of surge pricingincreasing fares dur-
ing high-demand periods—as price gouging.
40
Critics have argued that Uber
provides insufficient training for drivers and improperly classifies them as in-
dependent contractors rather than employees.
41
Passengers and taxicab compa-
37
See Ferenstein, supra note 27 (demonstrating that uberX ride-sharing is Uber’s most popular
service, as researchers found fifty-three percent of survey respondents were riding with uberX, as
opposed to an Uber limo, Lyft, Sidecar, or taxi); U
BER, supra note 29 (stating that Uber customers can
request a ride from an Uber-affiliated limo, taxi, or a lower-cost uberX vehicle). Lyft and Sidecar, on
the other hand, only offer ride-sharing vehicles. See L
YFT, supra note 29; SIDECAR, supra note 29.
38
See Ken Bensinger & Johana Bhuiyan, Uber Advises Drivers to Buy Insurance That Leaves
Them Uncovered, B
UZZFEED NEWS (Dec. 22, 2014), http://www.buzzfeed.com/kenbensinger/ubers-
yawning-insurance-gap?utm_term=.edjMADgPZ#.ubq9WDJbQz, archived at http://perma.cc/X6W4-
Q8A2 (reporting on an uberX driver recruiting event held at a car dealership); Lashinsky, supra note
34 (describing Uber’s strategy of partnering with dealerships and lenders to help uberX drivers with
poor credit finance new cars, getting them on the road faster); Douglas MacMillan, Uber Cuts Deals
to Lower Car Costs, W
ALL ST. J. (Nov. 25, 2013), http://blogs.wsj.com/digits/2013/11/25/uber-cuts-
deals-to-lower-car-costs/, archived at http://perma.cc/FF7G-8QZT (explaining that Uber partners with
Toyota, GM, and lenders to obtain discounts and financing for its drivers). It is possible that Uber
misleads uberX drivers about the insurance coverage they need so that it can recruit drivers more
quickly. See Bensinger & Bhuiyan, supra (reporting that an Uber representative told potential uberX
drivers that they do not need commercial auto insurance, which most drivers cannot afford).
39
See Boston Cab, 2014 WL 1338148, at *67 (alleging that Uber engages in unfair competition
by avoiding the costs of complying with taxi regulations); Saitto, supra note 12 (stating that Uber’s
strategy is to launch services without regard to regulations and then force local regulators to adapt).
Under Boston’s local regulations, for example, taxis must carry a hackney license, belong to a radio
association, and pass regular vehicle inspections and criminal background checks. See Boston Cab,
2014 WL 1338148, at *12 (stating that Boston’s Police Commissioner regulates taxis). See generally
B
OS. POLICE DEPT, RULE 403, supra note 24 (prescribing regulations for Boston taxis).
40
See Aratani, supra note 25 (stating that legislators are considering allowing taxis to engage in
surge pricing as well so that they can compete with Uber); Ben Walsh, Here’s Why Uber Is Tripling
Prices During a State of Emergency, H
UFFINGTON POST BUS. (Jan. 27, 2015, 12:59 PM), http://www.
huffingtonpost.com/2015/01/26/uber-price-surge-blizzard_n_6548626.html, archived at http://perma.
cc/93HR-ZQ55 (discussing criticism Uber faced after it raised prices during the terror attacks in Syd-
ney, Australia and Hurricane Sandy in the United States). Lyft also engages in surge pricing. Walsh,
supra.
41
See Richard Epstein, Uber and Lyft in California: How to Use Employment Law to Wreck an
Industry, F
ORBES (Mar. 16, 2015, 10:57 AM), http://www.forbes.com/sites/richardepstein/2015/03/
16/uber-and-lyft-in-california-how-to-use-employment-law-to-wreck-an-industry/, archived at http://
perma.cc/FGV9-XQJT (discussing two class action lawsuits against Uber pending in California that
challenge Uber’s practice of classifying drivers as independent contractors); Ellen Huet, Uber Skimps
on Driver Training, Then Charges Drivers $65 for Basic Driver Skills Course, F
ORBES (Oct. 28,
2014, 9:00 AM), http://www.forbes.com/sites/ellenhuet/2014/10/08/uber-skimps-on-driver-training-
then-charges-drivers-65-for-basic-driver-skills-course/, archived at http://perma.cc/9U2G-5S8W
[hereinafter Huet, Uber Skimps on Driver Training] (criticizing Uber for requiring drivers to pay for
their own training); Ellen Huet, What Happens to Uber Drivers and Other Sharing Economy Workers
Injured on the Job?, Forbes (Jan. 6, 2015, 1:15 PM), http://www.forbes.com/sites/ellenhuet/2015/01/
06/workers-compensation-uber-drivers-sharing-economy/, archived at http://perma.cc/9JUJ-ZS2Y
1106 Boston College Law Review [Vol. 56:1097
nies have sued Uber over its practice of charging mandatory driver gratuities
and taking its fees out of those gratuities.
42
Uber is also facing lawsuits over its
allegedly inadequate driver screening processes.
43
Finally, and most important-
ly for the purposes of this Note, the insurance industry has warned that Uber
does not provide drivers with adequate auto insurance.
44
But given that ride-
sharing appears to be the future of transportation, regulators are wary of over-
regulating TNCs and stifling innovation.
45
[hereinafter Huet, Sharing Economy Workers Injured on the Job] (questioning whether Uber properly
classifies drivers as independent contractors, as it allows Uber to avoid providing them with overtime
pay, worker’s compensation, sick days, and health insurance); London’s Anti-Uber Taxi Protest
Brings Traffic to Standstill, supra note 26 (reporting that the London taxi drivers intended their Uber
protest to highlight the intense training that taxi drivers undergo).
42
See Ehret, 2014 WL 4640170, at *1 (recounting a customer’s allegations that Uber misrepre-
sents its fees as a driver “gratuity”); Boston Cab, 2014 WL 1338148, at *2 (recounting the taxicab
dispatch companies’ allegations that Uber’s practice of charging customers a twenty percent gratuity,
and keeping half, exceeds the maximum fare taxicabs are allowed to charge).
43
See Andrew Lopez, Prices Slashed for UberX as Opposition Raise Questions Over Safety,
NBC
LOS ANGELES (June 23, 2014, 12:04 PM), http://www.nbclosangeles.com/news/local/UberX-
Cuts-Prices-as-Opposition-Raises-Questions-Over-Safety-264278051.html, archived at http://perma.
cc/W2ZY-VHB3 (pointing out that uberX drivers are not subject to the same background checks as
taxicab drivers); Kurt Orzeck, Calif. DAs Hit Uber with Consumer-Safety Suit as Lyft Settles, L
AW360
(Dec. 9, 2014), http://www.law360.com/articles/603221/calif-das-hit-uber-with-consumer-safety-suit-
as-lyft-settles, archived at http://perma.cc/J4BQ-PBJ5 (reporting that California authorities sued Uber
and Lyft for misleading consumers about the quality of their background checks).
44
See Commercial Ride-Sharing, supra note 13 (describing potential gaps in insurance coverage for
uberX and other ride-sharing drivers); Stephanie Friedhoff, Insurance Could Make Road Bumpy for Uber
and Lyft, B
OS. GLOBE (Jan. 7, 2015), available at http://www.bostonglobe.com/business/2015/01/
07/insurance-questions-latest-bump-road-for-ride-share-companies/wegXpHUBpZHwtUXNHJSf6H/
story.html, archived at http://perma.cc/MRF4-YK5T (stating that insurers opine that ride-sharing drivers
have sufficient auto insurance coverage).
45
See Steve Chapman, The Flimsy Case for Regulating Uber, CHI. TRIBUNE (Jan. 2, 2015, 4:00
PM), http://www.chicagotribune.com/news/opinion/chapman/ct-uber-regulation-background-pricing-
sexual-assault-perspec-0104-20150102-column.html, archived at http://perma.cc/RB4L-TF4N (argu-
ing against regulating Uber and contending that heavy regulation made the taxicab industry ineffi-
cient); Farhad Manjoo, Uber, a Rising Business Model That Could Change How You Work, N.Y.
TIMES (Jan. 28, 2015), http://www.nytimes.com/2015/01/29/technology/personaltech/uber-a-rising-
business-model.html, archived at http://perma.cc/GJ8L-7V5V (reporting on theuberization” of dif-
ferent types of jobs and noting that the number of new drivers on Uber’s platform doubles every six
months); Saitto, supra note 12 (reporting that app systems for hailing rides is here to stay and that
regulators should level the playing field for competitors); Harrison Weber, As Uber Battles 13 Law-
suits, Cabbies & State Agencies Are Out for Blood (Update), V
ENTUREBEAT (May 8, 2014), http://
venturebeat.com/2014/05/08/as-uber-battles-13-lawsuits-cabbies-state-agencies-are-out-for-blood/,
archived at http://perma.cc/A2ZR-8BXB (warning that the numerous lawsuits against Uber could hurt
innovation and potentially put all ride-sharing companies out of business); see also supra notes 6983
and accompanying text (discussing recent attempts to regulate ride-sharing).
2015] Uber’s Insurance Coverage and Unfair Competition Laws 1107
B. Mind the Gap: Potential Problems with UberX Drivers’
Insurance Coverage
Since uberX accidents have become more common, Uber has opened up
about its insurance coverage for ride-sharing drivers in an effort to ensure the
public that ride-sharing is safe.
46
Ubers customers appear fully covered for
their injuries; however, uberX driversaccess to compensation is less certain.
47
The uncertainty surrounding uberX drivers’ coverage while they are driving
around searching for fares is particularly problematic, as operating a mobile
phone app while driving is risky behavior.
48
Uber structures its insurance for
uberX drivers in the following way.
49
An uberX drivers insurance coverage varies depending on the drivers
activity, which can be divided into three distinct time periods.
50
During period
46
See Hourdajian, Eliminating Ridesharing Ambiguity, supra note 6 (announcing contingent
liability coverage for drivers during the trolling period in hopes of eliminating any confusion about
coverage that arose after an uberX driver accidentally killed a young girl in San Francisco); Zara
Rahim, Certificate of InsuranceU.S. Ridesharing, U
BER (Jan. 11, 2015), http://blog.uber.com/
certificatesofinsurance, archived at http://perma.cc/5ZBD-RMT2 (providing hyperlinks to Uber’s
insurance certificates for every state).
47
See Tim Fernholz, A Coverage Dispute Between Uber, Lyft, and Insurers Leaves Drivers Exposed,
Q
UARTZ (Mar. 23 2015), http://qz.com/365854/a-coverage-dispute-between-uber-lyft-and-insurers-
leaves-drivers-exposed/, archived at http://perma.cc/39Y7-KH8U (discussing the uncertainty that
remains over whether uberX drivers are covered by insurance while they drive around searching for
fares); Hourdajian, Insurance for uberX, supra note 8 (indicating that Uber has a commercial liability
policy that kicks in when the uberX driver accepts a fare request and continues through the duration of
the ride). But see Stephanie Francis Ward, Internet Car Companies Offer Convenience, but Lawyers
See Caution Signs, ABA
J. (Jan. 1, 2014 10:00AM), http://www.abajournal.com/magazine/article/
internet_car_companies_offer_convenience_but_lawyers_see_caution_signs, archived at http://perma.
cc/YM6B-C4WD (noting that some lawyers believe $1,000,000 will not go very far in a serious acci-
dent with multiple injured parties). Uber’s commercial liability policy will pay for up to $1,000,000 in
third party damages caused by the uberX driver and up to an additional $1,000,000 for injuries caused
by an underinsured third party driver. Hourdajian, Insurance for uberX, supra note 8.
48
See NAIC WHITE PAPER ON TNC INSURANCE, supra note 8, at 56 (explaining that most in-
surers and consumer protection groups believe that ride-sharing drivers post a greater risk during the
trolling period because they are required to use their cell phones); Badger, Strange Tale, supra note 7
(describing how an Uber driver, with the app on but without a passenger, struck another vehicle that
dislodged a fire hydrant and struck a pedestrian); Matt Richtel, Distracted Driving and the Risks of
Ride-Hailing Services Like Uber, N.Y. T
IMES (Dec. 21, 2014, 7:00 AM), http://bits.blogs.nytimes.
com/2014/12/21/distracted-driving-and-the-risks-of-ride-hailing-services-like-uber/, archived at http://
perma.cc/P8BN-7KAR (explaining how Uber drivers trolling for fares have fifteen seconds to manu-
ally respond to a ride request on the app or they risk losing the fare and access to Uber’s driver plat-
form); Sovern, supra note 5 (reporting that mother of young girl killed by uberX driver claimed to
have seen driver looking at his phone when he hit her daughter).
49
See infra notes 5068 and accompanying text (explaining uberX drivers’ insurance coverage).
50
See Hourdajian, Eliminating Ridesharing Ambiguity, supra note 6 (showing that uberX ride-
sharing insurance coverage varies based on whether the driver has the app off or on and whether the
driver has a passenger). Lyft has a nearly identical insurance structure. Compare id. (stating that an
uberX driver is covered by his or her personal insurance and Uber’s contingent liability policy while
the app is on but no ride is in progress, and then Uber’s full commercial liability coverage kicks in
once the driver accepts a ride request), with We Go the Extra Mile for Safety, L
YFT, https://www.lyft.
1108 Boston College Law Review [Vol. 56:1097
one, the driver is neither using the Uber app nor seeking fares.
51
Uber asserts
on its website that all drivers have auto insurance policies that cover them dur-
ing this time.
52
During period two, the uberX driver is logged into the Uber
app and seeking fares, but has not yet accepted a ride request.
53
Ubers website
states that the drivers personal policy is in effect during this period.
54
Uber
also carries a contingent liability policy that covers the driver in the event that
the drivers insurer denies coverage for an accident during period two.
55
Final-
ly, period three commences when the uberX driver accepts a ride request and
com/safety, archived at http://perma.cc/3CM9-FANC (last visited May 17, 2015) (stating that Lyft’s
contingent liability policy covers the driver while the app is on but no ride is in progress, and then
Lyft’s commercial liability coverage begins once the driver accepts a ride request).
51
See Hourdajian, Eliminating Ridesharing Ambiguity, supra note 6 (providing a visual of an
uberX driver’s insurance coverage over the course of a ride, indicating that Uber’s insurance is una-
vailable to drivers when the app is off). The uberX driver is essentially off-duty during this time. See
id.
52
See id. (indicating that uberX drivers have “personal auto insurance” coverage when the “Uber
app [is] off”). This Note is concerned with Uber’s assertions about ride-sharing drivers’ insurance
because many uberX drivers rely on Uber to tell them what insurance they need. See Bensinger &
Bhuiyan, supra note 38 (reporting that many uberX drivers rely on Uber’s representations about in-
surance because they are inexperienced with transportation). Most uberX drivers only carry personal
auto insurance, although some insurance officials believe that they should have commercial policies. See
id. (explaining that many uberX drivers do not have commercial insurance because it costs three to ten
times more than personal insurance); NAIC Consumer Alert for Ridesharing Drivers, supra note 8
(warning ride-sharing drivers that personal policies likely will not cover commercial activity, so they
should consider purchasing a commercial policy).
53
See Hourdajian, Eliminating Ridesharing Ambiguity, supra note 6 (indicating that a second
time period commences when the uberX driver logs into the app and is waiting for a trip request).
54
See id. (stating that when ride-sharing drivers have the Uber app on, “the vast majority of per-
sonal insurance policies cover this period either by the plain terms of the insurance policy, or due to
the insurance requirements set by state”); Hourdajian, Insurance for uberX, supra note 8 (stating that
[d]uring the time that a ridesharing partner is available but between trips, most personal auto insur-
ance will provide coverage”).
55
See Hourdajian, Insurance for uberX, supra note 8 (indicating that Uber’s “contingent liability
coverage” also covers uberX drivers while they search for fares for up to $50,000 in damages per
person, up to $100,000 in damages per incident, and up to $25,000 in property damage). Liability
polices pay for injuries to third parties that the driver causes but not for the driver’s own injuries.
R
OBERT H. JERRY, II & DOUGLAS R. RICHMOND, UNDERSTANDING INSURANCE LAW 918 (5th ed.
2007) (explaining liability coverage). Drivers must purchase first-party coverage if they intend to
insure their own medical expenses and property. See id. (explaining personal injury protection and
underinsured motorist, collision, and comprehensive coverages, all of which are first-party coverages).
Personal injury protection pays for the insured driver’s own medical expenses. Id. Underinsured mo-
torist coverage (“UI/UIM”) pays for the insured’s own medical expenses if another driver that lacks
sufficient liability policy injures the insured. Id. Finally, collision and comprehensive coverages com-
pensate the insured for damages to his or her property. Id. at 918, 96869 (explaining that collision
coverage pays for vehicular damage caused by impact with another object, whereas comprehensive
coverage pays for vehicular damage caused by other perils, such as a bridge collapse). Uber’s liability
policy for uberX drivers during the trolling period, which will only pay for third parties’ injuries, is
also “contingent” because it only pays if the driver’s personal auto insurer completely denies the claim
or pays nothing. See Hourdajian, Insurance for uberX, supra note 8.
2015] Uber’s Insurance Coverage and Unfair Competition Laws 1109
spans the duration of the ride.
56
During period three, Ubers website indicates
that its primary commercial liability policy covers uberX drivers.
57
Although Uber asserts that uberX drivers personal insurance covers them
while they drive around searching for fares (during period two), a coverage
gap may persist during this time.
58
Drivers personal policies usually do not
cover commercial activities.
59
In addition, most personal auto polices contain
express livery exclusions stating that the policy will not cover the insured if the
insured uses the vehicle to carry persons for a fee.
60
Trolling for fares alone
can trigger livery exclusions.
61
Therefore, insurers can refuse to provide uberX
drivers with coverage under their personal policies, or rescind their personal
policies entirely, if insurers discover that the drivers engaged in ride-sharing.
62
56
See id. (indicating that Uber’s commercial insurance coverage applies during a period begin-
ning from the moment the uberX driver accepts the trip until the trip is completed).
57
See id. (indicating that as soon as the uberX driver accepts a ride request, the driver is covered
by Uber’s commercial liability policy, as well as an additional $1,000,000 in UI/UIM motorist cover-
age, personal injury protection in select states, and contingent comprehensive and collision coverage
up to the value of the car). Uber’s commercial liability policy is “primary” because it takes precedence
over the uberX driver’s personal policy, but it will not take precedence over any commercial policy on
the vehicle. See id.
58
Compare id. (indicating that most uberX drivers’ personal policies will cover them when they
have the app on and are searching for fares), with Bensinger & Bhuiyan, supra note 38 (noting that
because personal policies issued by Allstate, State Farm, Progressive, and Geico do not cover any sort
of ride-sharing, some insurers have cancelled policies of drivers who engaged in ride-sharing), and
Ellen Huet, Rideshare Drivers Still Cornered into Insurance Secrecy, F
ORBES (Dec. 18, 2014, 2:45
PM) http://www.forbes.com/sites/ellenhuet/2014/12/18/uber-lyft-driver-insurance/, archived at http://
perma.cc/DC6F-3SSL [hereinafter Huet, Rideshare Drivers Cornered into Secrecy] (interviewing
ridesharing drivers, some of whose insurers dropped them because of their ride-share driving), and
Notice to Transportation Network Company Drivers, supra note 8 (advising drivers to get their own
commercial auto policies with first party coverages, particularly medical payments, comprehensive,
collision, and UI/UIM coverages, as TNCs’ insurance policies may leave coverage gaps).
59
See Mooney v. Nationwide Mut. Ins. Co., 822 A.2d 567, 569, 571 (N.H. 2003) (holding that
insurer was authorized to rescind insured’s personal policy because he put his car to commercial use
by delivering mail for his employer); J
ERRY & RICHMOND, supra note 55, at 917 (distinguishing be-
tween personal auto insurance and commercial auto insurance); NAIC Consumer Alert for Rideshar-
ing Drivers, supra note 8 (warning ride-sharing drivers that most personal policies contain livery
exclusions that do not cover commercial activities, so insurers may refuse to insure them if they con-
duct business with their personal vehicles).
60
See NAIC Consumer Alert for Ridesharing Drivers, supra note 8 (warning drivers that most
personal auto policies have livery exclusions, which may exclude the time period when the driver is
available for hire); Notice to Transportation Network Company Drivers, supra note 8 (providing the
language of the typical livery exclusion found in personal auto policies).
61
See Friedhoff, supra note 44 (noting that the insurance industry overwhelming opines that
trolling for rides is not covered by personal auto policies that contain a livery exclusion); Rassman,
supra note 10, at 88, 90 (discussing how commercial activity can trigger livery exclusions, despite
Uber’s claims that personal auto policies are effective, which leads to confusion over whether person-
al policies will cover uberX drivers while they drive around searching for fares).
62
See JERRY & RICHMOND, supra note 55, at 39197, 71723 (discussing insurers’ main justifi-
cations for terminating coveragemisrepresentation, breach of warranty, or concealmentand dis-
tinguishing representations from warranties). This risk of total loss of personal insurance leads some
ride-sharing drivers to lie to their insurers about their ride-sharing. See Friedhoff, supra note 44 (re-
1110 Boston College Law Review [Vol. 56:1097
Moreover, Ubers contingent liability policy does not compensate uberX
drivers for their own physical and property damages in the event of an acci-
dent.
63
The policy will not compensate uberX drivers for their bodily injury or
vehicle damage, because liability coverage only covers third party injuries that
the uberX drivers cause.
64
Further, Uber does not carry personal injury protec-
tion for drivers during this period, which would compensate uberX drivers for
their own bodily injuries regardless of fault.
65
Nor does Uber provide uberX
drivers with collision or comprehensive coverages, which would pay for dam-
age to the drivers vehicles.
66
Finally, Uber also lacks uninsured/underinsured
motorist (“UI/UIM) coverage for uberX drivers during this period.
67
UI/UIM
coverage would pay for uberX drivers injuries if a motorist without third-party
liability coverage caused the accident.
68
porting that some uberX drivers avoid telling their insurers that they drive for Uber to keep their per-
sonal coverage); Huet, Rideshare Drivers Cornered into Secrecy, supra note 58 (interviewing drivers
who lied to their personal auto insurers about engaging ride-sharing to avoid losing coverage).
63
See Fernholz, supra note 47 (reporting that insurers are pessimistic about Uber’s contingent
liability coverage for uberX drivers during the trolling period, which Uber claims fills any coverage
gap); Wallace, supra note 7 (reporting an Uber spokesperson’s statement that liability policies only
compensate injured third parties, not the injured uberX driver).
64
See JERRY & RICHMOND, supra note 55, at 918 (explaining that liability coverage is third-party
protection that compensates only injured third parties, whereas first-party protection compensates the
driver for his or her own injuries).
65
See id. at 918, 92324 (explaining personal injury protection and no-fault laws); Hourdajian,
Insurance for uberX, supra note 8 (displaying an uberX driver’s insurance coverage over the course of
a ride-sharing transaction, which lacks personal injury protection while the driver is searching for
fares). Many states mandate personal injury protection to ensure that drivers’ own injuries are com-
pensated. See J
ERRY & RICHMOND, supra note 55, at 97 (citing Tomai-Minogue v. State Farm Mut.
Auto. Ins. Co., 770 F.2d 1228, 1235 (4th Cir. 1985)) (explaining that states regulate the amount and
type of auto insurance coverage people must buy to ensure that injured persons have access to ade-
quate compensation); Summary of State Laws Related to Auto Insurance, N
ATL ASSN OF INS.
COMMRS, http://www.naic.org/documents/committees_c_d_auto_insurance_study_group_related_
auto_law_summary.pdf, archived at http://perma.cc/7RJN-FKNM (last visited May 17, 2015) (indi-
cating that seventeen states mandate drivers carry personal injury protection).
66
See JERRY & RICHMOND, supra note 55, at 918 (stating that comprehensive and collision are first-
party coverages that cover damage to the insured’s own vehicle); Hourdajian, Insurance for uberX, supra
note 8 (displaying an uberX driver’s insurance coverage over the course of a ride-sharing transaction,
which lacks comprehensive and collision coverages while the driver is searching for fares).
67
See Hourdajian, Insurance for uberX, supra note 8 (displaying absence of UI/UIM coverage for
uberX drivers while they are driving with the app on and searching for fares).
68
See JERRY & RICHMOND, supra note 55, at 918 (explaining that underinsured motorist cover-
age is a first-party coverage). UI/UIM coverage is required in most states. See Summary of State Laws
Related to Auto Insurance, supra note 65 (indicating that thirty-five states require drivers to carry
uninsured motorist coverage, although drivers in some states can reject the coverage in writing).
2015] Uber’s Insurance Coverage and Unfair Competition Laws 1111
C. Back to the Drawing Board: Recent Attempts to Regulate TNCs and
Ride-sharing Insurance
As Uber’s insurance practices have become more public, so too has the
discourse surrounding them.
69
Uber asserts that its insurance complies with the
law in all states, but because TNCs do not fit neatly into existing regulatory
frameworks for transportation, it is unclear which laws even apply.
70
Realizing
that Uber manages to deny insurance coverage for its drivers regularly, state
insurance commissioners and lawmakers have begun pursuing legislation that
will directly govern TNCs activities.
71
Although many of the proposed laws create specific insurance require-
ments for ride-sharing, some insurance officials believe that they may not go
far enough to protect uberX drivers.
72
California, for example, emerged as a
69
See, e.g., Don Jergler, Uber Announces New Policy to Cover Gap, INS. J. (Mar. 14, 2014),
http://www.insurancejournal.com/news/national/2014/03/14/323329.htm, archived at http://perma.cc/
97RY-XHU8 (reporting that the Property Casualty Insurers Association of America has been publicly
advocating for TNCs to fill the gaps in ride-sharing drivers’ insurance); Vara, supra note 7 (criticizing
Uber’s handling an insurance dispute arising from an accident involving an uberX driver that resulted
in death of young girl in San Francisco); Ward, supra note 47 (providing an overview of the various
legal issues, including lack of insurance coverage, that ride-sharing raises).
70
See Commercial Ride-Sharing, supra note 13 (stating that ride-sharing does not fit into insurers
risk-pooling models for personal auto insurance because the risks are not yet well understood; addi-
tionally, TNCs may not be subject to taxi and limo regulations that mandate proper insurance); Hour-
dajian, Insurance for uberX, supra note 8 (stating that Uber’s contingent liability policy in effect be-
tween trips “meets or exceeds the requirements for [third] party liability insurance in every state in the
U.S.,” and that personal injury protection “is provided in certain states at similar levels as limos or
taxis in those cities”). It is questionable whether Uber’s insurance for ride-sharing drivers does in fact
comply with local laws. Compare T
EX. INS. CODE ANN. § 1952.152 (West 2009) (mandating that all
insured carry personal injury protection coverage), with Certificate of Liability Insurance, U
BER (Dec.
19, 2014), https://uber-regulatory-documents.s3.amazonaws.com/insurance/COIs/TX.pdf, archived at
http://perma.cc/8AUD-AVMB (providing proof of Uber’s insurance coverage in Texas, which lacks
personal injury protection).
71
See Commercial Ride-Sharing, supra note 13 (noting that state insurance regulators are work-
ing with TNCs to ensure that drivers are adequately covered, even though insurance regulators usually
oversee insurance companies and agents); Jergler, supra note 69 (stating that Uber is working with
insurers and lawmakers to ensure that ride-sharing drivers have proper coverage). See generally
P
ROPERTY CAS. INSURERS ASSN OF AM., TRANSPORTATION NETWORK COMPANY (RIDE SHARING)
ISSUE STATUS (Aug. 8, 2014), available at http://www.naic.org/documents/cipr_events_140819_
tnc_issue_status.pdf, archived at http://perma.cc/E9WM-BFZ7 (listing states’ regulatory actions per-
taining to ride-sharing safety and insurance).
72
See, e.g., CAL. PUB. UTIL. CODE § 5433 (West Supp. 2015) (requiring TNC drivers to carry
certain minimum amounts of insurance starting (a) when the driver logs into the app, and (b) when the
driver accepts a ride request, but not stating who should maintain the policies and not mandating first-
party coverages for the driver); A.B. 6090, 2015 Assemb., 238th Legis. Sess. (N.Y. 2015) (proposing
to require TNCs in New York to: (a) provide first party coverage for drivers while they are transport-
ing passengers, without mentioning the trolling period; and (b) disclose to drivers that their personal
liability policies may not cover them while the TNC app is on, but not mentioning that their personal
first party benefits may be entirely unavailable as well); H.B. 931, 189th Gen. Court, Reg. Sess. (Ma.
2015) (proposing to require TNCs to (a) provide liability coverage to drivers that complies with Mas-
sachusetts’ mandatory minimums from the moment they turn the app on, but without mention first-
1112 Boston College Law Review [Vol. 56:1097
leader in the regulatory race following Sofia Liu’s death in San Francisco on
New Years Eve in 2013.
73
Starting on July 1, 2015, California will require
TNCs drivers to be covered by insurance starting the moment they log into the
app, even if they do not yet have a passenger.
74
The law also requires TNCs to
make certain disclosures to drivers in their driver agreements.
75
TNCs must
disclose the limits of their liability policies, and that drivers personal policies
will not cover them while they are using the TNCs’ platforms.
76
TNCs also
will no longer be able to provide coverage that is contingent upon drivers sub-
mitting claims to their personal insurers first.
77
California’s attempts to fill the
coverage gap during period two, when the uberX drivers are trolling for fares,
and educate ride-sharing drivers about their insurance are steps in the right di-
rection.
78
party coverages, and (b) disclose to drivers that their personal policies may not be in effect, but with-
out requiring the TNCs to provide any detail);
NAIC WHITE PAPER ON TNC INSURANCE, supra note
8, at 6 (noting that some states have enacted legislation to fill ride-sharing insurance coverage gaps,
but holes still remain).
73
See Nordman, supra note 6, at 67 (describing California’s Insurance Commissioner as the
leader in the insurance community with regard to regulating TNCs and discussing his recommenda-
tions); Dan Packel, Calif. Bill on Uber, Lyft Insurance Offers Road Map for Pa., L
AW360 (Aug. 29,
2014, 5:47 PM), http://www.law360.com/articles/572365/calif-bill-on-uber-lyft-insurance-offers-
road-map-for-pa, archived at http://perma.cc/PAF9-5MBT [hereinafter Packel, Calif. Bill] (reporting
that Pennsylvania legislators will look to California as they attempt to regulate ride-sharing insur-
ance); Vara, supra note 7 (reporting that California lawmakers were spurred into action by Sofia’s
death in San Francisco).
74
CAL. PUB. UTIL. CODE § 5433(b)(c) (imposing new insurance requirements on TNCs effective
July 1, 2015). “[F]rom the moment a participating driver logs on to the . . . platform until the driver
accepts a request . . . and from the moment . . . the ride is complete . . . until the driver . . . accepts
another ride request . . . [TNC] insurance shall be primary” and provide up to $50,000 for personal
injury per person, up to $100,000 for personal injury per accident, and up to $30,000 for property
damage Id. § 5433(c). Then, “from the moment a participating driver accepts a ride request . . . until
the driver completes the transaction . . . [TNC] insurance shall be primary and in the amount of one
million dollars ($1,000,000) for death, personal injury, and property damage.” Id. § 5433(b).
75
See id. § 5432 (imposing disclosure requirements effective July 1, 2015).
76
Id. § 5432(a)(b) (requiring that TNCs disclose in their driver agreements “the insurance cov-
erage and limits of liability that the [TNC] provides while the driver uses . . . [the TNC’s] platform,”
and that “the driver’s personal automobile policy will not provide collision or comprehensive cover-
age for damage to the [driver’s] vehicle . . . from the moment the driver logs on to the [TNC’s] . . .
platform to the member the driver logs off”). TNCs also must provide drivers written notice that their
“personal automobile insurance policy will not provide coverage because the driver uses a vehicle in
connection with a [TNC’s] . . . platform.” Id. § 5432(a).
77
Id. § 5433(d) (“Coverage under a [TNC] insurance policy shall not be dependent on a personal
automobile insurance policy first denying a claim nor shall a personal automobile insurance policy be
required to first deny a claim.”).
78
See Packel, Calif. Bill, supra note 73 (noting that Pennsylvania lawmakers, trial lawyers, and
insurers agreed that California’s new TNC insurance regulations would serve as a useful guide for
their state).
2015] Uber’s Insurance Coverage and Unfair Competition Laws 1113
Some insurance officials believe, however, that Californias law does not
fully protect uberX drivers interests.
79
The law does not dictate whether the
TNC or the driver must maintain the drivers’ insurance coverage required for
period two, while drivers are searching for fares.
80
Nor does the law require
drivers to be covered by first-party insurance during period two, which would
pay for the drivers’ own injuries.
81
Further, Californias required disclosures
about drivers’ insurance coverage may end up buried in fine print in the driver
agreements, making them of little use in educating drivers.
82
These potential
loopholes concern some insurance officials, as they want greater assurances
that these new laws will adequately inform and protect drivers.
83
79
See CAL. PUB. UTIL. CODE §§ 54325433 (discussing insurance coverage for TNC drivers but
not directly addressing first-party protection for drivers, adequate disclosures, and who must provide
drivers with coverage during the trolling period); cf. A.B. 3765, 216th Leg., 2014 Sess. (N.J. 2014)
(stating that the “[TNC] shall provide” drivers with commercial liability coverage, “property damage
and uninsured and underinsured motorist coverage, medical payments coverage . . . and optional col-
lusion and comprehensive coverage,” which “shall be in force and effect from the time the . . . provid-
er makes itself available for hire by logging into the [TNC]’s application . . . and continuing during
any transportation network trip . . . until the . . . provider logs out”).
80
CAL. PUB. UTIL. CODE § 5433(c)(1)(A)(C) (stating that requirements for insurance during the
trolling period “may be satisfied by . . . [TNC] insurance maintained by a participating driver” or
“insurance maintained by a [TNC] that provides coverage in the event a participating driver’s insur-
ance policy” fails to provide coverage). By contrast, New Jersey’s proposed law clearly states that
TNCs must provide coverage to ride-sharing drivers from the moment they log into the app through
the duration of every trip. See N.J. A.B. 3765 (stating that the “[TNC] shall provide coverage . . . to
the provider contracting with the [TNC]”).
81
See CAL. PUB. UTIL. CODE § 5433 (not discussing first party coverages for the driver, other
than requiring UI/UIM coverage to be in effect during a ride); J
ERRY & RICHMOND, supra note 55, at
918 (explaining first-party coverages). New Jersey, on the other hand, proposes to require TNCs to
provide drivers with “property damage and uninsured and underinsured motorist coverage, medical
payments coverage . . . and optional collusion and comprehensive coverage,” which must be in effect-
ing whenever the driver’s TNC app is on. See A.B. 3765.
82
See CAL. PUB. UTIL. CODE § 5432 (mandating only that disclosures must be in writing, and
some must be given in the driver agreements). New Jersey’s proposed disclosures will more effective-
ly warn ride-sharing drivers about the potential for insurance gaps. See A.B. 3765 (requiring explicit
disclosures to drivers about the insurance implications of ride-sharing, which must be “on a separate
sheet of paper,” “in 14-point bold type,” and “signed by the [driver]”).
83
See NAIC Consumer Alert for Ridesharing Drivers, supra note 8 (providing ride-sharing driv-
ers with questions to ask TNCs about their insurance coverage and advising them to talk to their per-
sonal insurers); Packel, Lyft, Uber Ridesharing Bids, supra note 11 (noting that Pennsylvania insur-
ance officials have criticized TNCs for not providing ride-sharing drivers with “adequate insurance
education”). But see Fernholz, supra note 47 (quoting an Uber representative as stating “it’s up to
[drivers] to be able to read their own personal insurance policy to see if it works”).
1114 Boston College Law Review [Vol. 56:1097
II. KEEPING THEM HONEST: FIGHTING UNFAIR BUSINESS PRACTICES WITH
UNFAIR COMPETITION LAWS
When companies act unethically, unfair competition laws play an important
role in righting the wrongs of the company.
84
To determine whether Uber Tech-
nologies, Inc. (“Uber”) engages in an unfair business practice when it makes
assertions about uberX insurance, it is important to examine the standards courts
use to determine whether a business practice is unfair.
85
As such, Section A of
this Part discusses California’s unfair competition law (“UCL”) and explains
why California law is appropriate for evaluating Ubers insurance practices.
86
Section B then explains how California courts distinguish between UCL lawsuits
brought by business competitors versus consumers.
87
Finally, Section C exam-
ines the different tests for unfairness that courts use to assess competitor and
consumer UCL claims.
88
A. Giving the Public a Voice: California’s Unfair Competition Law
California’s UCL is the proper law under which to analyze possible uberX
driver claims against Uber for unfair competition for two reasons.
89
First, alt-
hough the Federal Trade Commission Act (“FTCA”) also prohibits unfair
competition by businesses, it does not provide a private right of action.
90
As
such, most states, including California, have adopted similar unfair competi-
84
See Federal Trade Commission Act, 15 U.S.C. § 45(a)(1) (2012) (“Unfair methods of competi-
tion in or affecting commerce, and unfair or deceptive acts or practices in or affecting commerce, are
hereby declared unlawful.”); H.R.
REP. NO. 103-138, at 24 (1993) (discussing the purpose underly-
ing the Federal Trade Commission Act (“FTCA”) of protecting consumers from unfair business prac-
tices on both a case-by-case and industry-wide basis); Helfman, supra note 12, at 22829 (explaining
that unfair business practices could not be controlled through common law, so Congress enacted sec-
tion five of the FTCA, and many states followed suit). State unfair competition laws serve as powerful
tools for consumers, who cannot enforce the FTCA. Helfman, supra note 12, at 229.
85
Compare Hourdajian, Eliminating Ridesharing Ambiguity, supra note 6 (stating that uberX
drivers should feel confident that they do not have any insurance gaps), with NAIC Consumer Alert for
Ridesharing Drivers, supra note 8 (warning ride-sharing drivers about the potential gaps in their in-
surance).
86
See infra notes 89104 and accompanying text.
87
See infra notes 105115 and accompanying text.
88
See infra notes 116179 and accompanying text.
89
See CAL. BUS. & PROF. CODE §§ 17200–17203 (West 2012) (providing that [a]ny person who
engages . . . in unfair competition may be enjoined,” and “unfair competition shall mean and include
any unlawful, unfair or fraudulent business act or practice and unfair, deceptive, untrue or misleading
advertising and any act prohibited by Chapter 1 . . . of Part 3 of Division 7 of the Business and Profes-
sions Code”).
90
15 U.S.C. § 45(a)(2) (stating that “[t]he [FTC] is hereby empowered and directed to prevent
persons . . . from using unfair methods of competition in or affecting commerce and unfair or decep-
tive acts or practices in or affecting commerce”); see Helfman, supra note 12, at 229 (noting that the
FTCA does not provide a private right of action).
2015] Uber’s Insurance Coverage and Unfair Competition Laws 1115
tion statutes to give consumers a way to sue businesses acting unfairly.
91
Sec-
ond, California law is likely to apply to uberX drivers claims against Uber
because Ubers driver agreements contain a California choice of law provi-
sion.
92
Therefore, this Note focuses on Uber’s potential liability to uberX driv-
ers under California’s UCL.
93
Like many other unfair competition laws, California’s UCL prohibits “un-
fair . . . business act[s] or practice[s],” among other types of unethical behav-
ior.
94
The UCL purports to ameliorate the societal harm caused by businesses
acting unethically in a variety of contexts.
95
Almost any conduct in commer-
cial markets for goods and services constitutes a business practice under the
UCL.
96
Both public prosecutors and private individuals can sue under the
91
See, e.g., CAL. BUS. & PROF. CODE §§ 1720317204 (providing that [a]ny person who engag-
es . . . in unfair competition may be enjoined,” “by [any] person who has suffered injury in fact and
has lost money or property as a result of the unfair competition”); 815 I
LL. COMP. STAT. ANN. 505/2,
505/10a (2012) (stating that “[u]nfair methods of competition and unfair or deceptive acts or practices
. . . in the conduct of any trade or commerce are hereby declared unlawful,” and that “[a]ny person
who suffers actual damage as a result of a violation of this Act committed by any other person may
bring an action against such person”); M
ASS. GEN. LAWS ch. 93A, §§ 2(a), 9(1) (2012) (stating that
“unfair methods of competition and unfair or deceptive acts or practices in the conduct of any trade or
commerce are hereby declared unlawful,” and “[a]ny person . . . who has been injured . . . may bring
an action in the superior court”); see also Helfman, supra note 12, at 22930 (describing how many
states have adopted unfair competition statutes modeled after the FTCA or one of the three model
statutes promulgated by the FTC).
92
See O’Connor v. Uber Tech., Inc., No. C133826, 2014 WL 4382880, at *1, *11 (N.D. Cal.
Sept. 4, 2014) (upholding Uber’s contractual choice of law provision, but ultimately refusing to apply
California law extraterritorially); Ehret v. Uber Tech., Inc., No. C140113, 2014 WL 4640170, at *1,
*45 (N.D. Cal. Sept. 17, 2014) (allowing an out-of-state consumer’s UCL claims against Uber to
proceed).
93
See infra notes 94243 and accompanying text (analyzing Uber’s potential liability to uberX
drivers under California’s UCL).
94
CAL. BUS. & PROF. CODE §§ 17200, 17203; see 815 ILL. COMP. STAT. ANN. 505/2; MASS.
GEN. LAWS ch. 93A, § 2(a). California’s UCL proscribes many types of unfair competition, including
unfair business practices, unlawful business practices, fraudulent business practices and misleading
advertising. See C
AL. BUS. & PROF. CODE § 17200. Although these prongs of liability are not mutual-
ly exclusive, this Note is only concerned with the “unfair” business practices prong of liability. See
infra notes 95243 and accompanying text; see also Sharon J. Arkin, The Unfair Competition Law
After Proposition 64: Changing the Consumer Protection Landscape, 32 W.
ST. U. L. REV. 155, 157
(2005) (explaining that although the California UCL has multiple prongs of liability, the vast majority
of lawsuits are predicated on unlawful, unfair, and/or fraudulent business practices).
95
See Cel-Tech Commc’ns, Inc. v. L.A. Cellular Tel. Co., 973 P.2d 527, 53940 (Cal. 1999)
(stating that the “sweeping” language of the UCL gives courts latitude to enjoin new, creative unfair
business schemes as they arise); Arkin, supra note 94 (discussing the UCL’s broad intent to protect all
of society, including business competitors and the consuming public).
96
See Celebrity Chefs Tour, LLC, v. Macys, Inc., 16 F. Supp. 3d 1159, 116970 (S.D. Cal. 2014)
(holding that distributing a television show for broadcast constituted a business practice); Drum v. San
Fernando Valley Bar Ass’n, 106 Cal. Rptr. 3d 46, 48, 5152 (Cal. Ct. App. 2010) (treating the bar associ-
ation’s refusal to sell its membership list as a business practice and applying several tests for unfairness
under the UCL). But see Tecza v. Univ. of S.F., 532 Fed. App’x 667, 66869 (9th Cir. 2013) (holding that
disclosure of a student’s private medical information was not a business practice).
1116 Boston College Law Review [Vol. 56:1097
UCL.
97
To establish standing, plaintiffs must demonstrate that the business
practice that caused them economic injury that is at the core of the claim.
98
The
bar for demonstrating a cognizable injury under California’s UCL is very
low.
99
Restitution and injunctive relief are the only remedies available to indi-
vidual plaintiffs, however, because courts assume that plaintiffs will seek dam-
ages through other legal avenues.
100
The standard California courts use to evaluate whether conduct is unfair
depends on whether the plaintiff is a competitor or a consumer.
101
A competitor
alleging unfair business practices must prove that the conduct violated antitrust
97
CAL. BUS. & PROF. CODE § 17204 (stating that “[a]ctions for relief pursuant to this chapter shall
be prosecuted . . . by the Attorney General or a district attorney . . . or by a person who has suffered injury
in fact and has lost money or property as a result of the unfair competition”).
98
See id.; Kwikset Corp. v. Superior Court, 246 P.3d 877, 88485 (Cal. 2011) (explaining the
UCL’s standing requirements). Plaintiffs whose claims are based on a business’s misrepresentations
must also demonstrate actual reliance to have standing. See In re iPhone Application Litig., 6 F.
Supp. 3d 1004, 1015 (N.D. Cal. 2013) (dismissing plaintiffs’ UCL claims for failure to establish actu-
al reliance on the defendant’s misrepresentations about its data collection and privacy practices). Cali-
fornia’s UCL did not require plaintiffs to demonstrate any injury until voters passed Proposition 64 in
2004, which tightened the UCL standing provisions to require plaintiffs to demonstrate an injury in
fact. See 2004 Cal. Legis. Serv. Prop. 64 (West) (codified as amended at C
AL. BUS. & PROF. CODE
§§ 17203, 17204, 17206, 17535, 17536 (West 2012)); Arkin, supra note 94, at 156, 16769 (explaining
that Proposition 64 requires plaintiffs to demonstrate an actual economic injury, not merely a prospec-
tive or possible injury, because plaintiffs’ attorneys abused the UCL).
99
See Kwikset, 246 P.3d at 88586 (stating that the economic injury requirement is not difficult
to satisfy; it can even consist of overpaying in a transaction). Most states with unfair competition laws
require plaintiffs to demonstrate an actual economic injury in order to have standing. See Camasta v.
Jos. A. Bank Clothiers, Inc., 761 F.3d 732, 740 (7th Cir. 2014) (interpreting “actual damage” require-
ment of Illinois’s unfair competition statute to require the plaintiff to demonstrate actual pecuniary
loss, such as paying more for an item than it is worth); Helfman, supra note 12, at 233 (indicating that
most states predicate standing for unfair competition lawsuits on actual injury). But see Ruiz v. Bally
Total Fitness Holding Corp., 496 F.3d 1, 5 (1st Cir. 2007) (holding that an injury sufficient to estab-
lish standing under Massachusetts’s unfair competition statute can consist of an economic or non-
economic loss).
100
See CAL. BUS. & PROF. CODE §§ 17203, 17205 (stating that anyone who “engage[s] in unfair
competition may be enjoined”; that “[a]ny person may pursue representative claims for relief on be-
half of others only if the claimant meets the standing requirements”; and “the remedies or penalties
provided by this chapter are cumulative to each other and to the remedies or penalties available under
all other laws of this state”); Cel-Tech, 973 P.2d at 539 (noting that private plaintiffs’ UCL remedies
are limited to injunctive relief and restitution); Helfman, supra note 12, at 23233 (stating that states
enacted unfair competition laws to enjoin bad business behavior because common law remedies were
not always effective). Public prosecutors can also seek civil penalties under the UCL. C
AL. BUS. &
PROF. CODE § 17206 (providing that “[a]ny person who engages . . . in unfair competition shall be
liable for a civil penalty . . . which shall be assessed and recovered in a civil action brought in the
name of the people of the State of California by the Attorney General” or other public prosecutors).
101
See Drum, 106 Cal. Rptr. 3d at 51 (noting that the test for unfair business practices differs based
on whether the plaintiff is a competitor or a consumer of the defendant). Whether a business practice is
unfair under the UCL is a factual issue. Countrywide Fin. Corp. v. Bundy, 113 Cal. Rptr. 3d 705, 723
(Cal. Ct. App. 2010).
2015] Uber’s Insurance Coverage and Unfair Competition Laws 1117
law or policy or otherwise harmed competition.
102
A consumer, however, can
establish unfairness under three different standards used by the appellate
courts.
103
Regardless of which standard applies, the legislature intended courts
to construe the UCLs unfairness prong broadly to allow them to strike down
new, harmful business schemes as they arise.
104
B. Friend or Foe?: Distinguishing Between Consumer and Business
Competitor UCL Claims
Courts evaluating claims under the UCLs unfairness prong must first de-
cide whether the plaintiffs are competitors or consumers of the defendants,
because competitors must satisfy a stricter standard of unfairness.
105
If plain-
tiffs allege that the defendants’ actions harmed their particular businesses or
competition generally, courts will treat them as competitors of the defend-
ant.
106
For example, in 1999, in Cel-Tech Communications, Inc. v. Los Angeles
102
See Cel-Tech, 973 P.2d at 544 (adopting a standard for unfair business practices that applies
when a plaintiff brings a UCL claim against a direct competitor, which is grounded in antitrust princi-
ples). Anticompetitive practices tend to reduce competition and are the target of antitrust legislation.
See id. at 54354 (looking to the FTCA and federal antitrust law to determine what constitutes anti-
competitive conduct); Neil W. Averitt, The Meaning of “Unfair Methods of Competition” in Section 5
of the Federal Trade Commission Act, 21 B.C.
L. REV. 227, 23841 (1980) (explaining that violations
of the Sherman Act, such as price fixing, and Clayton Act, such as forming an agreement that will
create a monopoly, can serve as the basis for unfair competition lawsuits under the FTCA).
103
See Drum, 106 Cal. Rptr. 3d at 5354 (describing three lines of consumer UCL cases that
emerged after the Supreme Court of California decided Cel-Tech Communications, Inc. v. Los Angeles
Cellular Telephone Co. in 1999, all applying different standards for unfairness). The Supreme Court of
California has not decided which test is proper in consumer lawsuits. Id. at 53.
104
See Cel-Tech, 973 P.2d at 540 (stating that the legislature intended the standard for unfairness
to be broad enough to allow courts to enjoin “innumerable new schemes which the fertility of man’s
invention would contrive”) (internal quotation marks omitted); People ex rel. Mosk v. Nat’l Research
Co. of Cal., 20 Cal. Rptr. 516, 52021 (Cal. Ct. App. 1962) (stating that because unfair business
schemes “may run the gamut of human ingenuity and chicanery,” the legislature must have intended
the UCL to be inclusive); Helfman, supra note 12, at 23133 (explaining that the purpose of state
unfair competitions laws is to provide a broader cause of action with broader remedies than the
FTCA).
105
See, e.g., Rankin v. Global Tel*Link Corp., No. 13cv01117JCS, 2013 WL 3456949, at *16
(deciding to treat plaintiff as a competitor rather than consumer before applying the competitor test for
unfairness); Cel-Tech, 973 P.2d at 544 & n.12 (Cal. 1999) (adopting a narrow, antitrust policy-based
standard for unfairness for competitor lawsuits and stating that nothing in the opinion relates to con-
sumer actions); Progressive W. Ins. Co. v. Yolo Cnty. Superior Court, 37 Cal. Rptr. 3d 434, 453 (Cal.
Ct. App. 2005) (opining that the narrower standard of unfairness used in competitor cases is inappro-
priate for consumer cases because consumers are more vulnerable than businesses). Some courts will
avoid deciding whether a plaintiff is a consumer or competitor if they find that the plaintiff failed to
meet either standard of unfairness. See Drum, 106 Cal. Rptr. 3d at 51 (holding that the court need not
determine whether the plaintiff was a competitor or consumer because the plaintiff failed to satisfy
either standard of unfairness).
106
See, e.g., Levitt v. Yelp! Inc., 765 F.3d 1123, 113637 (9th Cir. 2014) (applying the competi-
tor standard of unfairness because the plaintiffs were business owners who claimed the defendant’s
actions hurt their business prospects); Rankin, 2013 WL 3456949, at *16 (utilizing the competitor test
1118 Boston College Law Review [Vol. 56:1097
Cellular Telephone Co., the Supreme Court of California treated the plaintiff
and defendant as competitors under the UCL.
107
The plaintiff, a cell phone re-
tailer, accused another cell phone retailer of below-market pricing, an anti-
competitive practice.
108
Similarly, in 2014, in Levitt v. Yelp! Inc., the Ninth
Circuit for the U.S. Court of Appeals held that the plaintiff and defendant were
competitors.
109
Although the small business owners who sued Yelp! Inc. did
not compete with the defendant directly, they alleged harm to competition as a
result of Yelp!’s conduct.
110
If the plaintiffs suing under the unfair business practices prong of the
UCL do not claim that the defendants caused them business injuries or en-
gaged in anti-competitive activities, however, the court will treat them as con-
sumers.
111
As such, California courts have treated defendants’ employees and
customers both as consumers for the purposes of their UCL claims.
112
For in-
stance, in 2012 in Aleksick v. 7-Eleven, Inc., California’s Fourth District Court
of Appeal treated a franchise employee as a consumer in her suit against the
franchisor based on its payroll practices.
113
Likewise, in 2014 in Ehret v. Uber
Technologies, Inc., the U.S. District Court for the Northern District of Califor-
of unfairness because the plaintiff alleged that the defendant monopolized the market); Cel-Tech, 973
P.2d at 54446 (holding that the competitor standard of unfairness applied to the cell phone seller’s
claims that its direct competitor sold cell phones at a loss to drive the plaintiff out of business).
107
See Cel-Tech, 973 P.2d at 545 (applying the competitor standard of unfairness).
108
Id. at 53233.
109
See Levitt, 765 F.3d. at 1136 (applying the competitor standard of unfairness after the small
business owners conceded its applicability to their claims).
110
See id. (noting that although the small business owners did not compete with Yelp!, they al-
leged a loss of competitiveness); see also Rankin, 2013 WL 3456949, at *16 (treating the plaintiff bail
bond company as a business competitor because the first amended complaint alleged harm to competi-
tion); First Amended Complaint at 10, Rankin, 2013 WL 3456949 (3:13-cv-01117-JCS) (alleging that
the disruption in defendant’s telephone services damaged the plaintiff’s business and hurt competition
within the bail bonds industry).
111
See, e.g., Ehret, 2014 WL 4640170, at *10 (treating the plaintiff as a consumer because she
argued that the fees she paid to Uber were unfair); McKell v. Wash. Mut., Inc., 49 Cal. Rptr. 3d 227,
24041 (Cal. Ct. App. 2006) (treating the plaintiffs as consumers because they alleged that their mort-
gage lender overcharged borrowers for underwriting); Wilner v. Sunset Life Ins. Co., 93 Cal. Rptr. 2d
413, 42223 (Cal. Ct. App. 2000) (treating the plaintiff policyholder as a consumer because she
claimed her insurer’s deceptive sales tactics were unfair).
112
See, e.g., Donohue v. Apple, Inc., 871 F. Supp. 2d 913, 916, 928 (N.D. Cal. 2012) (applying a
consumer standard for unfairness to an Apple customer’s claims); Aleksick v. 7-Eleven, Inc., 140 Cal.
Rptr. 3d 796, 80708 (Cal. Ct. App. 2012) (applying a consumer standard for unfairness to the fran-
chise employee’s claims against a franchisor); Wilner, 93 Cal. Rptr. at 42223 (applying the consumer
standard of unfairness in to the policyholder’s claims against the insurer from whom she purchased
insurance). To be considered a consumer under the UCL, a plaintiff need not transact business with
the defendant, but he or she must be able to establish standing. See Camacho v. Auto. Club of S. Cal.,
48 Cal. Rptr. 3d 770, 773, 779 (Cal. Ct. App. 2006) (treating a debtor as a consumer in his lawsuit
against a debt collector for its collection practices, but dismissing his case because he lacked an inju-
ry).
113
Aleksick, 140 Cal. Rptr. at 80708 (applying the consumer standard of unfairness to the em-
ployee’s claims that the franchisor’s payroll practices deprived her of income).
2015] Uber’s Insurance Coverage and Unfair Competition Laws 1119
nia treated a rider suing Uber over its fees as a consumer.
114
Because courts
subject consumers to different standards of unfairness, determining whether
plaintiffs are competitors or consumers is a threshold issue for courts.
115
C. All Plaintiffs Are Not Created Equal: Different Standards of Unfairness
for Business Competitors and Consumers Suing Under the UCL
California courts apply different standards to determine whether business
activities are unfair under the UCL depending on whether the plaintiff is a busi-
ness competitor or a consumer.
116
For claims brought by competitors, courts ap-
ply a narrow antitrust standard of unfairness referred to as the Cel-Tech test.
117
Most competitor claims are dismissed under this test, however, because it is dif-
ficult to plausibly plead harm to competition.
118
California courts apply three different tests to determine unfairness in
UCL claims brought by consumers, however, because the Supreme Court of
California has not yet adopted a uniform standard.
119
Accordingly, this Section
114
Ehret, 2014 WL 4640170, at *10 (applying the consumer standard of unfairness to the cus-
tomer’s claims that she paid more for the transaction than she would have if Uber had not misrepre-
sented its fees).
115
See Rankin, 2013 WL 3456949, at *16 (deciding that the plaintiff was a competitor before
analyzing whether the defendant’s conduct was unfair under the competitor standard). But see Drum,
106 Cal. Rptr. at 51, 54 (refusing to decide whether the plaintiff was a competitor or consumer yet
affirming the dismissal for failure to state a UCL claim).
116
See Zhang v. Superior Court, 304 P.3d 163, 174 n.9 (Cal. 2013) (pointing out the various
standards for unfairness that appellate courts apply to consumer UCL actions); Cel-Tech, 973 P.2d at
544 & n.12 (adopting a new test for unfairness to be used in competitor UCL lawsuits but stating that
its opinion does not apply to consumer lawsuits).
117
Cel-Tech, 973 P.2d at 544 (holding that a business practice is unfair to competitors if it
“threatens an incipient violation of an antitrust law, or violates the policy or spirit of one of those laws
. . . or otherwise significantly threatens or harms competition”). Since Cel-Tech, courts have applied
this anticompetitive standard for unfairness to all UCL claims brought by competitors. See, e.g., Levitt,
765 F.3d at 1136 (applying the Cel-Tech test for unfairness to business competitors’ UCL claims);
Rankin, 2013 WL 3456949, at *16 (same); Drum, 106 Cal. Rptr. 3d at 51 (same).
118
See, e.g., Levitt, 765 F.3d at 113637 (dismissing small business owners’ allegations that
Yelp! harmed competition by manipulating ratings of certain business because plaintiffs failed to
demonstrate how it violated antitrust principles); Rankin, 2013 WL 3456949, at *16 (dismissing bail
bond company’s claims against prison telephone service provider because plaintiff failed to demon-
strate that defendant created a monopoly or otherwise violated antitrust law); Drum, 106 Cal. Rptr. 3d
at 5152 (dismissing plaintiff’s claim based on defendant’s refusal to sell him its mailing list because
an independent actor refusing to deal does not implicate antitrust law, even if it affects prices). But see
Cel-Tech, 973 P.2d at 546 (remanding the case for trial, noting that the unusual circumstances might
satisfy the new standard for unfairness). Pleading harm to one’s business prospects is insufficient to
satisfy the Cel-Tech standard of unfairness. See id. at 544 (noting that “injury to a competitor” does
not establish harm to competition or implicate antitrust law).
119
See Lozano v. AT&T Wireless Servs., Inc., 504 F.3d 718, 736 (9th Cir. 2007) (observing that
the California courts have not yet decided what is the standard for unfair business practices when
consumers sue under the UCL, and explaining three different standards that have emerged); Zhang,
304 P.3d at 174 n.9 (noting that Cel-Tech did not resolve the issue of which standard for unfairness
applies in consumer actions); see also Camacho, 48 Cal. Rptr. 3d at 77677 (applying the “section 5
1120 Boston College Law Review [Vol. 56:1097
examines the different consumer tests for unfairness available to plaintiffs.
120
Subsection 1 describes the balancing test for unfairness, which predated Cel-
Tech.
121
Subsection 2 discusses a policy-based standard of unfairness that some
courts adopted after Cel-Tech, which this Note refers to as the revised Cel-
Tech test.”
122
Lastly, Subsection 3 explains the section 5 testfor unfairness,
which some courts developed by looking to the FTCA, just as Cel-Tech did.
123
1. The Balancing Test for Unfair Business Practices
Many California courts apply a balancing test to determine if a business
practice is unfair to consumers under the UCL.
124
Under the balancing test,
courts weigh the utility of the conduct against the gravity of the harm to the
consumer.
125
Conduct is unfair if it violates established public policy or if it is
immoral, unethical, oppressive or unscrupulous and causes injury to consumers
which outweighs its benefits.”
126
This balancing test previously applied to all
plaintiffs’ allegations of unfair business practices, until Cel-Tech held in 1999
that competitors must use a narrower test.
127
Thus, not surprisingly, some low-
test” for unfairness to a consumer’s UCL claim, based on the FTCA’s definition of unfair business
practices); Gregory v. Albertson’s, Inc., 128 Cal. Rptr. 2d 389, 395 (Cal. Ct. App. 2002) (applying a
test (that this Note refers to as the revised Cel-Tech test) which defines unfair business practices as
violative of a public policy that is tied to specific legislation); Wilner, 93 Cal. Rptr. 2d at 42223 (ap-
plying the balancing test for unfair business practices).
120
See infra notes 124179 and accompanying text.
121
See infra notes 124154 and accompanying text.
122
See infra notes 155169 and accompanying text.
123
See infra notes 170179 and accompanying text.
124
See, e.g., McKell, 49 Cal. Rptr. 3d at 240 (holding that test for unfairness involves weighing
utility of defendant’s conduct against harm to plaintiff); Progressive, 37 Cal. Rptr. 3d at 453 (conclud-
ing that balancing test should apply in consumer actions, and allowing case to proceed so that defend-
ant could present evidence justifying its seemingly unethical practice); Wilner, 93 Cal. Rptr. 2d at 422
(holding that the test for whether a practice is unfair to consumers involves balancing the impact on
the plaintiff against the defendant’s justifications for the conduct).
125
See Wilner, 93 Cal. Rptr. 2d at 422.
126
McKell, 49 Cal. Rptr. 3d at 240. In 2000, in Wilner v. Sunset Life Insurance Co., California’s
Second District Court of Appeal framed the test slightly differently, stating that conduct is unfair if it
“offends an established public policy” or “is immoral, unethical, oppressive, unscrupulous or substan-
tially injurious to consumers” (emphasis added) (internal quotation marks omitted). Wilner, 93 Cal.
Rptr. 2d at 422.
127
See Cel-Tech, 973 P.2d at 543 (holding that the balancing test for unfairness no longer applies
in competitor claims because it is “too amorphous” to provide meaningful guidance to businesses).
Cel-Tech also described the balancing test that lower courts use to define unfairness. Id.; see State
Farm Fire & Cas. Co. v. Superior Court, 53 Cal. Rptr. 2d 229, 23435 (Cal. Ct. App. 1996) (stating
that courts “must weigh the utility of the defendant’s conduct against the gravity of harm to the al-
leged victim”) (internal quotation marks omitted); People v. Casa Blanca Convalescent Homes, Inc.,
206 Cal. Rptr. 164, 177 (Cal. Ct. App. 1994) (stating that a business practice is unfair if it “offends an
established public policy or when the practice is immoral, unethical, oppressive, unscrupulous or
substantially injurious to consumers”); Motors, Inc. v. Times Mirror Co., 162 Cal. Rptr. 543, 546
(Cal. Ct. App. 1980) (stating that determining “whether a particular business practice is unfair neces-
2015] Uber’s Insurance Coverage and Unfair Competition Laws 1121
er courts still hold that the balancing test is proper for evaluating unfairness in
consumer claims, as Cel-Tech did not deal with consumers.
128
Although the
balancing test is imprecise,
its flexibility allows courts greater discretion to
protect consumers, who are more vulnerable to abuse than business competi-
tors.
129
This flexible balancing test allows courts to intervene when a business
engages in a pattern of misleading the public.
130
For example, in 2000, in Wil-
ner v. Sunset Life Insurance Co., California’s Second District Court of Appeal
held that an insurer’s sales practices were unfair under the UCL.
131
Sunset Life
Insurance Co. (Sunset) convinced customers to replace their existing whole or
term life insurance, bought from other companies, with Sunsets universal life
insurance by deceiving them about their benefits and premiums.
132
Further, Sun-
set failed to determine whether universal life insurance was suitable for the
new customers and concealed the inferiority of the product, despite knowing
that the product was inappropriate for most people.
133
Weighing the harm to
the deceived policyholders against Sunset’s lack of justification for its “im-
moral, unethical and unscrupulous sales practices, the court found the practice
was unfair under the UCL.
134
sarily involves an examination of its impact on its alleged victim, balanced against the reasons, justifi-
cations and motives of the alleged wrongdoer”).
128
See, e.g., Progressive, 37 Cal. Rptr. 3d at 453 (Cal. Ct. App. 2006) (applying the balancing
test because (1) Cel-Tech did not disapprove of its use in consumer claims, (2) the state Supreme
Court has not yet overruled it, and (3) the statutory term “unfair” should be construed broadly to fulfill
the legislative intent); McKell, 49 Cal. Rptr. 3d at 240 (applying the balancing test); Wilner, 93 Cal.
Rptr. 2d at 422 (applying the balancing test).
129
See Cel-Tech, 973 P.2d at 543 (calling the balancing test “vague”); Progressive, 37 Cal. Rptr.
3d at 453 (stating that the balancing test should apply in consumer actions because its broad reach
enables courts to better protect consumers, who lack resources to protect themselves from unscrupu-
lous businesses); see also Leslie E. Schuster, For the “Deals” No Shopper Could Pass Up: The Ninth
Circuit’s Interpretation of California’s False Advertising Law in Hinjos v. Kohl’s Corporation, 47
L
OY. L.A. L. REV. 1049, 10561058 (2014) (discussing the psychological factors that influence con-
sumer behavior and decision-making).
130
See, e.g., Ehret, 2014 WL 4640170, at *1 (noting the plaintiff’s allegation that the transporta-
tion network company had a pattern of disguising its fees as driver gratuities); McKell, 49 Cal. Rptr.
3d at 234 (noting that the mortgage lender had a pattern of overcharging mortgagors for underwrit-
ing); Progressive, 37 Cal. Rptr. 3d at 43839 (describing the plaintiff’s allegations that the insurer had
a pattern of demanding reimbursement without regard to whether it was legally entitled to the money);
Wilner, 93 Cal. Rptr. 2d at 416, 422 (finding that the insurer had a pattern of selling unsuitable re-
placement insurance policies to new customers).
131
Wilner, 93 Cal. Rptr. 2d at 422.
132
Id. at 42224. Sunset tricked customers into believing that their replacement policies provided
greater death benefits for the same (or lower) premiums than their existing policies, when in fact the
premiums for the replacement policies would certainly rise. Id. at 423.
133
Id. at 422. The court noted that Sunset’s deceptive methods for selling the policies to new
customers differed from the procedures it followed when selling the policies to preexisting customers.
Id. at 423. For its preexisting customers, Sunset conducted suitability determinations and cost-benefit
analyses for the policyholders before selling them universal life insurance. Id.
134
Id. at 42324 (citing State Farm, 53 Cal. Rptr. 2d at 235).
1122 Boston College Law Review [Vol. 56:1097
Similarly, in 2006, in Progressive West Insurance Co. v. Yolo County Su-
perior Court, Californias Third District Court of Appeal applied the balancing
test and allowed an insureds UCL claim against his insurer to proceed.
135
Pro-
gressive West Insurance Co. (“Progressive”) misrepresented its rights with re-
spect to policyholders and demanded reimbursements to which it was not nec-
essarily entitled.
136
Just as in Wilner, the court deemed the insurers practice
immoral, unethical, oppressive, unscrupulous or substantially injuriousto
claimants.
137
It also noted that Progressive had not yet provided a reason or
motive to justify its practices.
138
Thus, the court held that the plaintiff properly
stated a claim under the unfairness prong of the UCL.
139
Courts also use the balancing test to protect consumers from businesses
that disguise their costs and fees.
140
For instance, in 2006, in McKell v. Wash-
ington Mutual, Inc., Californias Second District Court of Appeal allowed a
homeowners’ UCL suit to proceed against their mortgage lender for its misrep-
resenting underwriting costs.
141
The lender misled borrowers about the cost of
the federal governments automated underwriting program, charging them sub-
stantially more for the service than it cost.
142
The lender’s defense, that the
court should not get involved with its fee practices because lending is already
heavily regulated, did not justify the harm it caused homeowners from failing
to pass on savings accrued from automatic underwriting
143
Further, the lenders
overcharging homeowners undermined established federal public policy aimed
at increasing home ownership by making underwriting cheaper and faster.
144
Therefore, the court held that the lender’s fees were potentially unfair under
the UCL.
145
135
Progressive, 37 Cal. Rptr. 3d at 43839, 453.
136
Id. at 453. The plaintiff alleged that the insurer acted in bad faith by seeking full reimburse-
ment of medical payments from payees, even though multiple common law doctrines limit an insur-
er’s right to reimbursement. Id. at 43839.
137
Id. at 453 (internal quotation marks omitted).
138
Id.
139
Id. at 450.
140
See Ehret, 2014 WL 4640170, at *910 (holding that the Uber customer stated a UCL claim
against the transportation network company for disguising its fees as driver gratuities); McKell, 49
Cal. Rptr. 3d at 235, 237 (holding that the mortgage holder stated a UCL claim against the lender for
disguising the true cost of underwriting from customers).
141
McKell, 49 Cal. Rptr. 3d at 235, 237.
142
Id. at 235. The lender charged borrowers hundreds of dollars for automated underwriting and did
not disclose that it actually only cost the bank twenty dollars to perform. Id. The bank also charged some
borrowers for underwriting services that it did not provide. Id.
143
Id. at 241
144
See id. at 235, 24041 (explaining the federal policy underlying the automatic underwriting
program as increasing homeownership by lowering borrowing costs, reducing underwriting risks, and
speeding up the process).
145
See id. at 241 (holding that the plaintiffs sufficiently alleged unfair business practices under
the UCL); see also State Farm, 53 Cal. Rptr. 2d at 235 (stating that a business practice is unfair if it
“offends established public policy”).
2015] Uber’s Insurance Coverage and Unfair Competition Laws 1123
Likewise, in Ehret, the court used the balancing test to allow the Uber
passengers UCL claim against Uber to proceed.
146
Uber represented to riders
that the twenty percent fee tacked on to all fares was a driver gratuity, when in
fact Uber kept a substantial portion of that fee.
147
Applying the balancing test
for unfairness, the court noted that Uber provided no justification for the prac-
tice that could outweigh the plaintiffs injury, i.e., that she paid more than she
would have for the transaction but for Uber’s misrepresentations.
148
Therefore,
Ubers practice of disguising fees as driver gratuities was at least arguably un-
fair, and the customer’s UCL claim was allowed to proceed.
149
On the other hand, a company’s poor product design alone is unlikely to
satisfy the balancing test for unfair business practices.
150
For example, in 2012,
in Donohue v. Apple, Inc., the U.S. District Court for the Northern District of
California dismissed a customers UCL claim against his cell phone’s manu-
facturer.
151
The customer alleged that the manufacturer, Apple, Inc. (“Apple”)
designed a new signal meter that artificially inflated the phones apparent sig-
nal strength.
152
The court applied the balancing test and determined that Ap-
ple’s use of a faulty signal meter in its phones was not “immoral, unethical,
oppressive or unscrupulousabsent evidence that Apple intended to mislead or
146
Ehret, 2014 WL 4640170, at *10.
147
Id. Uber keeps half of the driver “gratuity,” or ten percent of the overall fare. Boston Cab
Dispatch, Inc. v. Uber Techs., Inc., No. 13-10769-NMG, 2014 WL 1338148, at *2 (D. Mass. Mar. 27,
2014).
148
Boston Cab, 2014 WL 1338148, at *6, *10 (describing the plaintiff’s alleged injury as surren-
dering more in the transaction than she otherwise would have due to Uber’s misrepresenting its fees as
driver gratuities). The fact that the twenty percent fee was mandatory did not factor in determining
whether the plaintiff’s injury was sufficient to establish standing. Id. at *7.
149
See id. at *7. (allowing the plaintiff’s UCL claim to proceed because no evidence existed at
the motion to dismiss stage of Uber’s justification for calling its fees driver gratuities); see also State
Farm, 53 Cal. Rptr. 2d at 234 (stating that to test whether a business practice is unfair, courts must
weigh the wrongdoer’s justifications against the victim’s injury).
150
See Donohue, 871 F. Supp. 2d at 928 (dismissing the plaintiff’s UCL claim based on the new
design of the phone’s signal meter because there existed no evidence that the manufacturer purpose-
fully designed the signal meter to artificially inflate signal strength). There was no precedent showing
that a poor product design, without related misrepresentations or knowledge of the product design’s
danger, can constitute an unfair business practice. Id.; cf. Peterson v. Mazda Motor of Am., Inc., 44 F.
Supp. 3d 965, 973 (C.D. Cal. 2014) (holding that the consumer adequately stated claim under the
unfairness prong of the UCL because the vehicle manufacturer knew that the cars had an assembly
defect that would likely result in dangerous and costly engine problems for buyers, and the manufac-
turer had not argued the utility of its conduct).
151
Donohue, 871 F. Supp. 2d at 928.
152
Id. at 927 (describing the plaintiff’s UCL claim based on the flawed signal meter design).
Instead of incorporating formulas recommended by wireless network providers to determine signal
strength of the phones, Apple developed its own secret formula based on a series of tests that, in retro-
spect, were flawed. Id. at 917. Apple publicly acknowledged and fixed its signal meter design flaw
soon after the product launched. Id.
1124 Boston College Law Review [Vol. 56:1097
deceive customers about connectivity.
153
Therefore, the court found the design
was not unfair under the UCL.
154
2. The Revised Cel-Tech Test for Unfair Business Practices
As an alternative to the balancing test, a series of consumer UCL cases
use a policy-based test for unfairness adapted from the competitor test laid out
in Cel-Tech.
155
Under this revised Cel-Tech test, a business practice is unfair to
consumers if it violates a public policy that is “‘tethered to specific constitu-
tional, statutory or regulatory provisions.”
156
Lower courts justified adopting
this new test by pointing to language in Cel-Tech, which criticized the balanc-
ing test as “too amorphous,” and reading such criticisms as overruling the bal-
ancing test entirely.
157
By requiring a public policy violation to be tethered to a
specific law, the revised Cel-Tech test addresses the Supreme Court of Califor-
nia’s concerns about vagueness, making for a stricter alternative to the balanc-
ing test.
158
153
Id. at 928 (noting that without facts showing that Apple knowingly installed a flawed signal
meter or made misrepresentations about it, the court will not get involved); see McKell, 49 Cal. Rptr.
3d at 240 (stating that a business practice is unfair if it is “immoral, unethical, oppressive or unscrupu-
lous”) (internal quotation marks omitted); cf. Peterson, 44 F. Supp. 3d at 973 (noting the plaintiff’s
allegations that the manufacturer knew that its engine design put the public safety at risk).
154
Donohue, 871 F. Supp. 2d at 92728.
155
Compare Graham v. Bank of Am., N.A., 172 Cal. Rptr. 3d 218, 23334 (Cal. Ct. App. 2014)
(adopting what this Note refers to as the revised Cel-Tech test and stating that an unfair business prac-
tice must be “tethered” to a specific law or public policy), and Aleksick, 140 Cal. Rptr. 3d at 807 (stat-
ing that an unfair competition claim must be predicated on a public policy that is tied to a specific
law), with Cel-Tech, 973 P.2d at 544 (defining unfair business practices as violating or threatening to
violate antitrust law or policy).
156
See Gregory, 128 Cal. Rptr. 2d at 395 (establishing the revised Cel-Tech test for unfairness)
(quoting Cel-Tech, 973 P.2d at 543).
157
Cel-Tech, 973 P.2d at 543 (referring to the definitions of unfairness under the balancing test as
“too amorphous and provid[ing] too little guidance to courts and businesses”); see Gregory, 128 Cal.
Rptr. 2d at 39495, 395 n.3 (disapproving of other California courts that continue to apply the balanc-
ing test and reading Cel-Tech as signaling that the balancing test for unfairness is too vague in any
context); see also Graham, 172 Cal. Rptr. 3d at 23334 (following the Gregory rationale and rejecting
the balancing test); Aleksick, 140 Cal. Rptr. 3d at 807 (same). Critics of the revised Cel-Tech test disa-
gree, and point out that the Supreme Court of California explicitly stated that it did not want Cel-
Tech’s narrow test to apply to consumers. See Cel-Tech, 973 P.2d at 544 n.12 (“This case involves an
action by a competitor alleging anticompetitive practices. Our discussion and this test are limited to
that context. Nothing we say relates to actions by consumers . . . .”); Progressive, 37 Cal. Rptr. 3d at
543 (refusing to apply the Cel-Tech language to consumer actions because the Supreme Court explic-
itly declined to extend its holding to consumers).
158
Compare Cel-Tech, 973 P.2d at 543 (stating that “vague references to ‘public policy,’ for
example, provide little real guidance”), and Scripps v. Superior Court, 134 Cal. Rptr. 2d 101, 11618
(Cal. Ct. App. 2003) (applying the revised Cel-Tech test to the consumer’s action because, as the Cel-
Tech court pointed out, it is the role of the legislature, not the courts, to decide which business practic-
es are unfair), and Gregory, 128 Cal. Rptr. 2d at 395 (holding that under the revised Cel-Tech test,
unfair business practices must violate a public policy that is “tethered” to a specific law because Cel-
Tech cautions against using the broader balancing test), with McKell, 49 Cal. Rptr. 3d at 240 (applying
2015] Uber’s Insurance Coverage and Unfair Competition Laws 1125
Although the revised Cel-Tech test is arguably broader than the test for
unfairness applied to competitors, it may undermine the broad purpose of the
UCL, because it is difficult for consumers to overcome.
159
For example, in
2002, in Gregory v. Albertson’s, Inc., Californias Second District Court of Ap-
peal applied the revised Cel-Tech test and dismissed a citizen’s UCL claim
against a grocery chain.
160
There, the plaintiff alleged that the decision of Albert-
son’s, Inc. (“Albertson’s”) to keep its leasehold space unoccupied to prevent a
competitor from moving in was unfair under the UCL.
161
She alleged that this
decision caused the entire surrounding shopping center to deteriorate, in viola-
tion of public policy against urban blight found in California’s Health and Safety
Code’s Community Redevelopment Law.
162
The court rejected these arguments
as a matter of law, because to enforce the policy against urban blight would in-
fringe on a separate state policy favoring freedom of contract.
163
Noting that the
plaintiffs remaining allegations failed to sufficiently invoke antitrust policy or
law, the court found that Albertson’s conduct was not unfair.
164
the balancing test, which states that a business practice is unfair if it “violates established public poli-
cy” and does not require tethering the policy to a law).
159
See Cel-Tech, 973 P.2d at 540 (stating that the legislature used “sweeping language” in the
UCL to give courts broad latitude to enjoin a wide range of unethical conduct); Camacho, 48 Cal.
Rptr. 3d at 776 (refusing to require consumer claims under the UCL’s unfairness prong to be tethered
to a legislative provision because it would undermine the broad purpose of UCL); see also Aleksick,
140 Cal. Rptr. 3d at 80708 (holding that a franchisor’s method of calculating employees’ wages was
not unfair because the Labor Code provisions invoked did not apply to the franchisor); Gregory, 128
Cal. Rptr. 2d at 395 (finding that a grocery chain’s decision to keep its store unoccupied to prevent
competitors from moving in was not unfair because the law that the plaintiff invoked did not provide a
private right of action). Still, the revised Cel-Tech test is arguably more flexible than the Cel-Tech
competitor test because almost any policy violation tied to a law can serve as the basis for claim, not
just antitrust policy or law. Compare Cel-Tech, 973 P.2d at 544 (holding that unfair business practices
must implicate antitrust policy or law) (emphasis added), with Gregory, 128 Cal. Rptr. 2d at 395
(holding that unfair business practices can implicate any public policy, as long as the policy is
grounded in a specific law).
160
Gregory, 128 Cal. Rptr. 2d at 397.
161
Id. at 39596.
162
Id. at 395. The Community Redevelopment Law provides a means for the public to redevelop
empty private property. See C
AL. HEALTH & SAFETY CODE § 33035 (West 2010); Gregory, 128 Cal.
Rptr. 2d at 395.
163
Gregory, 128 Cal. Rptr. 2d at 39596. The court noted that awarding an injunction against the
grocery chain, Albertson’s, would force them to enter into a commercial transaction. Id.
164
Id. The plaintiff did not allege violation of any specific antitrust law, and her allegation that
Albertson’s acted with the motive of thwarting competition was insufficient; rather, she needed to
allege that its conduct adversely affected competition. See id. Her allegation that the conduct reduced
market choices also did not demonstrate diminished competition. See id. If the court had applied the
balancing test to the allegations in Gregory, however, the case may have come out differently. See
McKell, 49 Cal. Rptr. 3d at 240 (explaining the balancing test); Gregory, 128 Cal. Rptr. 2d at 39091
(stating the plaintiff’s allegations against the grocery store chain). Albertson’s decision to leave its
storefront empty for potentially the forty years remaining on its lease seems to violate the state’s pub-
lic policy against urban decay, which was established by laws favoring efficient use of land. See
McKell, 49 Cal. Rptr. 3d at 240 (stating that under the balancing test, “[a] business practice is unfair
1126 Boston College Law Review [Vol. 56:1097
Similarly, in Aleksick, the court used the revised Cel-Tech test to dismiss a
franchise employee’s UCL claim against franchisor 7-Eleven, Inc. (“7-
Eleven”).
165
The employee alleged that 7-Eleven’s payroll calculation methods
violated the public policy favoring full payment of wages for all hours worked
found in California’s Labor Code.
166
The court held that the Labor Code provi-
sions did not apply to 7-Eleven, however, because 7-Eleven was a franchisor,
not an employer; thus, the plaintiffs allegations failed as a matter of law.
167
The payroll methods were therefore not unfair under the UCL.
168
Considering
the outcomes in Gregory and Aleksick, the revised Cel-Tech test may bar con-
sumer actions that the legislature would want to proceed.
169
. . . if it violates established public policy”); Gregory, 128 Cal. Rptr. 2d at 395 (explaining how the
Community Redevelopment Law allows the government to acquire vacant property through eminent
domain and spend public funds to redevelop it). Albertson’s actions also harm the consuming public
without good reason; it forced people to travel farther to get groceries because Albertson’s refused to
operate in the space or let another grocery store move in. See McKell, 49 Cal. Rptr. 3d at 240 (stating
that “the court must weigh the utility of the defendant’s conduct against the gravity of the harm to the
alleged victim”) (internal quotation marks omitted); Gregory, 128 Cal. Rptr. 2d at 39091 (noting the
plaintiff’s allegation that Albertson’s only justification for it conduct was to secure an advantage over
competitors, which Albertson’s did not rebut).
165
See Aleksick, 140 Cal. Rptr. 3d at 79899, 80708.
166
Id. at 798, 80708. 7-Eleven required all of its franchise stores to use a truncation method of
calculating payroll for their employees. Id. at 798. The plaintiff alleged that this practice violated several
provisions of the Labor Code that pertain to overtime pay, unpaid wages, and minimum wages. Id. at
801.
167
Id. at 802, 808. The plaintiff conceded that 7-Eleven, as a franchisor, was not her employer. Id.
at 806.
168
Id. at 808. If the court had applied the balancing test for unfairness to the employee’s UCL
claim in Aleksick, the case may have survived summary judgment. See id. at 79899 (alleging that 7-
Eleven’s payroll practices unfairly denied the franchise employees part of their wages, in violation of
Labor Code provisions that purport to ensure fair wage practices); McKell, 49 Cal. Rptr. 3d at 240
(stating that under the balancing test, “[a] business practice is unfair . . . if it violates established pub-
lic policy”). On the other hand, however, 7-Eleven asserted that truncating wages was easier to do on
the computers, and its expert opined that truncating did not reduce employee wages in the majority of
pay periods. See Aleksick, 140 Cal. Rptr. 3d at 798800 (describing the evidence and noting that the
plaintiff sought to represent a class of injured 7-Eleven franchise employees); McKell, 49 Cal. Rptr.
3d at 240 (stating that the court must “examin[e] . . . [the] impact on its alleged victim, balanced
against the reasons, justifications and motives of the alleged wrongdoer”) (internal quotation marks
omitted).
169
See Aleksick, 140 Cal. Rptr. 3d at 808 (affirming summary judgment for the defendant); Greg-
ory, 128 Cal. Rptr. 2d at 397 (affirming judgment on the pleadings in favor of defendant); Arkin,
supra note 94, at 157 (noting that the purpose of the UCL and its predecessor, California Civil Code
section 3369, is to protect the entire consuming public, so the law should not be applied narrowly); see
also Camacho, 48 Cal. Rptr. 3d at 776 (stating that requiring unfair business practices to be tethered
to a legislative provision undermines the broad purpose of the UCL, as well as the principle that a
practice can be “unfair” without being “unlawful”); Progressive, 37 Cal. Rptr. 3d at 543 (refusing to
require unfair business practices to be tethered to a specific law because the unfairness prong of the
UCL is supposed to be interpreted broadly to provide adequate protection to vulnerable consumers).
2015] Uber’s Insurance Coverage and Unfair Competition Laws 1127
3. The Section 5 Test for Unfair Business Practices
Instead of employing the balancing test or revised Cel-Tech test, a few
California courts evaluate consumer UCL claims using the definition of unfair
competition found in section five of the FTCA.
170
Under this section 5 test,a
business practice is unfair if: (1) the consumer suffered a substantial injury, (2)
that he or she could not reasonably avoid, and (3) the benefits of the business
practice do not outweigh the injury.
171
Courts that have adopted the section 5
test also read Cel-Tech as overturning the balancing test.
172
Taking a cue from
Cel-Tech dicta, these courts look to the FTCA and import its definition of un-
fairness into consumer claims under the unfair business practices prong of the
UCL.
173
These courts assert that the section 5 test is narrower than the flexible
balancing test, thereby assuaging the Supreme Court of Californias concerns
about ambiguity.
174
Further, the section 5 test avoids the pitfalls of importing
Cel-Techs narrow competitor standard of unfairness into consumer cases.
175
170
See, e.g., Zuniga v. Bank of Am. N.A., No. CV 1406471, 2014 WL 7156403, at *6 (C.D.
Cal. 2014) (citing Camacho, 48 Cal. Rptr. 3d at 77677) (adopting the three-pronged test for unfair-
ness delineated in section 5 of the FTCA); Davis v. Ford Motor Credit Co., 101 Cal. Rptr. 3d 697, 700
(Cal. Ct. App. 2009) (stating that the test for unfairness, laid out in 2006 by California’s Second Dis-
trict Court of Appeal in Camacho v. Automobile Club of Southern California, guides its inquiry);
Camacho, 48 Cal. Rptr. 3d at 77677 (rejecting the revised Cel-Tech test and coining the section 5 test,
based on the factors that define unfair competition under the FTCA); see also Federal Trade Commis-
sion Act § 5(n), 15 U.S.C. § 45(n) (2012)) (defining an act as unfair if it “causes or is likely to cause
substantial injury to consumers which is not reasonably avoidable by consumers themselves and not
outweighed by countervailing benefits to consumers or to competition”).
171
15 U.S.C. § 45(n); Camacho, 48 Cal. Rptr. 3d at 77677 (looking to the FTCA for guidance
and adopting the “section 5 test”).
172
See, e.g., Zuniga, 2014 WL 7156403, at *6 (finding Camacho’s rationale for adopting the
section 5 test convincing and finding unpersuasive the reasoning of courts that apply the revised Cel-
Tech test and courts that refuse to admit that Cel-Tech overruled the balancing test); Ford, 101 Cal.
Rptr. 3d at 700 (following Camacho’s reasoning for adopting the section 5 test); Camacho, 48 Cal.
Rptr. 3d at 77677 (stating that the balancing test cannot be satisfactory for consumer cases if the
Supreme Court of California deemed it too vague for competitor cases, and then adopting the section
5 test); see Cel-Tech, 973 P.2d at 543 (stating that the preexisting definitions of unfair business prac-
tices “are too amorphous and provide too little guidance to courts and businesses . . . we must devise a
more precise test for determining what is unfair”).
173
See Camacho, 48 Cal. Rptr. 3d at 77677 (explaining that Cel-Tech instructed the court to
look to the FTCA for guidance in interpreting the UCL’s unfairness prong, and noting that the FTCA
definition of unfairness is geared toward consumers); see also Cel-Tech, 973 P.2d at 564 (stating that
in order to devise a new test for unfairness, the court “may turn for guidance to the jurisprudence
arising under the parallel section 5 of the [FTCA]”) (internal quotation marks omitted).
174
See Zuniga, 2014 WL 7156403, at *6 (adopting the section 5 test, reasoning that the Supreme
Court of California’s concerns about the ambiguity of the balancing test spill over into consumer ac-
tions); Camacho, 48 Cal. Rptr. 3d at 77778 (describing the section 5 test as “suitably broad” but
“more focused” than the older definitions of unfairness, thereby making it easier to apply); see also
Ford, 101 Cal. Rptr. 3d at 70809 (agreeing with Camacho’s analysis and adopting the section 5 test).
For example, Camacho held that a collection agency’s attempts to collect a valid debt from the plaintiff
were not unfair under the section 5 test, as the plaintiff could have avoided incurring the debt by obeying
the law in the first place. Camacho, 48 Cal. Rptr. 3d at 779. Similarly, in 2009 in Davis v. Ford Motor
1128 Boston College Law Review [Vol. 56:1097
Some courts caution against adopting the section 5 test for unfair business
practices in consumer UCL actions, however, because the Supreme Court of
California has not endorsed the test.
176
Although the Cel-Tech court looked to
the FTCA for guidance in developing its competitor standard of unfairness, it
only referenced the FTCA case law dealing with direct competitor lawsuits.
177
Additionally, the Supreme Court of California has twice declined to rule on the
applicability of the section 5 test to consumers.
178
As such, the section 5 test
for unfairness under the UCL may be inappropriate for consumer actions.
179
III.
TIME TO COME CLEAN: UBERX DRIVERS CAN HOLD UBER
ACCOUNTABLE FOR ITS INSURANCE MISREPRESENTATIONS
U
SING CALIFORNIAS UNFAIR COMPETITION LAW
Uber Technologies, Inc. (Uber”)’s misrepresentations to uberX drivers
about their insufficient insurance coverage for ride-sharing violates the prohi-
bition against unfair business practices in Californias unfair competition law
Credit Co., California’s Second District Court of Appeal applied the section 5 test and held that the lend-
er’s billing practices were not unfair because the consumer could have avoided the successive late fees by
making his monthly payments on time. Ford, 101 Cal. Rptr. 3d at 700.
175
See Cel-Tech, 973 P.2d at 544 & n.12 (stating that its newly devised test for unfairness under
the UCL, i.e., that the conduct must violate an antitrust law or the “spirit” of one of those laws, is
limited to competitor lawsuits); Camacho, 48 Cal. Rptr. 3d at 77677 (refusing to apply Cel-Tech’s
“tethering” requirement to consumer cases because it would not serve the broad purpose of the UCL,
and describing the section 5 test as “suitably broad”); Progressive, 37 Cal. Rptr. 3d at 453 (stating that
requiring consumers to tether an alleged public policy violation to a specific law, as in Cel-Tech, un-
dermines the goals of the UCL). For instance, in 2014, in Zuniga v. Bank of America N.A., the U.S.
District Court for the Central District of California applied the section 5 test and found that the lender’s
dual-tracking foreclosure practice was unfair. Zuniga, 2014 WL 7156403, at *810. Although the plain-
tiff homeowner was responsible for defaulting on the loan, she could not avoid dual-tracking, which
caused her injury. Id. at *9. Furthermore, dual-tracking did not produce a benefit that outweighed the
plaintiff’s injury; in fact, the legislature tried to ban dual-tracking to keep people in their homes. Id.
176
See Lozano, 504 F.3d at 736 (refusing to adopt the section 5 test for unfairness in the absence
of a clear holding from the Supreme Court of California); Donohue, 871 F. Supp. 2d at 928 (same).
177
See Cel-Tech, 973 P.2d at 54344, 544 n.11 (stating that the court was only referencing FTCA
law that interpreted unfair competition in the consumer context). The court then stated that nothing in
its discussion pertained to consumer lawsuits and that it had no opinion on FTCA cases involving
consumers. Id. at 544 n.12. In 2007, in Lozano v. AT & T Wireless Services, Inc., the U.S. Court of
Appeals for the Ninth Circuit stated that the FTCA definition of unfairness does not provide appropri-
ate guidance for consumer actions because it involves anticompetitive conduct. Lozano, 504 F.3d at
736.
178
See Rose v. Bank of Am., 304 P.3d 181, 187 n.9 (Cal. 2013), cert. denied, 134 S. Ct. 2870
(2014) (noting that the lower court applied three different tests for unfairness, but refusing to address
the issue because it was not fully briefed); Zhang, 304 P.3d at 174 n.9 (noting that the appellate courts
use different tests for unfair business practices in consumer UCL lawsuits, including the section 5 test,
but declining to decide which test is proper).
179
See Lozano, 504 F.3d at 736 (stating that it is not appropriate to apply the FTCA test to con-
sumers without guidance from the Supreme Court of California). But see Camacho, 48 Cal. Rptr. 3d
at 777 (opining that because the FTCA definition of unfairness is “on its face geared to consumers,” it
is appropriate for consumer UCL actions).
2015] Uber’s Insurance Coverage and Unfair Competition Laws 1129
(“UCL).
180
Uber misrepresents to uberX drivers that the combination of their
personal policies plus Ubers contingent liability policy covers them complete-
ly while they drive around searching for fares.
181
In reality, Uber knows that
uberX drivers personal policies will not cover such commercial activity.
182
Moreover, even if an uberX driver obtains coverage through Ubers contingent
liability policy, it will not cover the drivers own bodily injuries or property
damage under any circumstance.
183
As a result, if uberX drivers cause acci-
180
See CAL. BUS. & PROF. CODE §§ 17200, 17203 (West 2012) (stating thatunfair competition
shall mean and include any unlawful, unfair or fraudulent business act or practice,” and “[a]ny person
who engages . . . in unfair competition may be enjoined”); Packel, Lyft, Uber Ridesharing Bids, supra
note 11 (reporting that Pennsylvania insurers opine that transportation network companies (“TNCs”)
still do not provide their drivers with adequate insurance or education about insurance); Hourdajian,
Insurance for uberX, supra note 8 (displaying the insurance coverage that uberX drivers have when
they are searching for fares, specifically their personal auto insurance plus Uber’s contingent liability
coverage).
181
Compare NAIC Consumer Alert for Ridesharing Drivers, supra note 8 (warning ride-sharing
drivers about remaining gaps in their insurance coverage, as most personal policies contain livery
exclusions), and Rassman, supra note 10, at 90 (quoting the Insurance Federation of Pennsylvania’s
opinion that Uber’s policy of offering only contingent liability coverage during the trolling period will
create confusion and leaves ride-sharing drivers exposed), with Hourdajian, Eliminating Ridesharing
Ambiguity, supra note 6 (stating that the “vast majority” of uberX drivers’ personal insurance policies
cover the trolling period, but if an insurer denies coverage, Uber’s contingent policy will provide
coverage). Lyft could be held liable under the unfair business practices prong of the UCL as well
because it provides drivers with the same insurance structure as uberX drivers. See We Go the Extra
Mile for Safety, supra note 50 (explaining Lyft’s insurance policies for ride-sharing drivers). Lyft also
has only contingent liability coverage in place for drivers during the time period while they are driving
around with the app on searching for fares. Id.
182
See NAIC Consumer Alert for Ridesharing Drivers, supra note 8 (warning drivers that making
themselves available for hire may trigger the livery exclusion in their personal policies); Friedhoff,
supra note 44 (reporting that insurance industry insiders disagree with Uber’s statements on its web-
site and instead believe uberX drivers are not covered by personal insurance while they drive around
looking for passengers); Packel, Lyft, Uber Ridesharing Bids, supra note 11 (reporting that Uber
knows about the problems with personal insurance policies that uberX drivers face). Despite this
knowledge, Uber requires uberX drivers to submit claims to their personal insurers before they can
access Uber’s contingent liability coverage. See Hourdajian, Insurance for uberX, supra note 8 (stating
that Uber’s contingent liability policy will only cover uberX drivers if their personal auto insurers
decline coverage or pay nothing). This contingency forces uberX drivers to choose between disclosing
their ride-sharing to their personal auto insurers to get the added coverage from Ubers contingent liabil-
ity policy, which risks losing their personal policies entirely), or submitting claims to their personal insur-
ers without disclosing their commercial activities. See Huet, Rideshare Drivers Cornered into Secrecy,
supra note 54 (discussing the dilemma that ride-sharing drivers face after getting into an accident
between lying to their insurer or risk losing their personal auto coverage). Lying on an insurance
claim, which some drivers do, constitutes insurance fraud. See id. (reporting how an uberX driver lied
to her personal insurer about ride-sharing when submitting her claim); Michael S. Quinn, Closing
Arguments in Insurance Fraud Cases, 23 T
ORT & INS. L.J. 744, 745 (1988) (noting that insureds
commit insurance fraud if they knowingly fail to disclose that they are engaged in riskier behaviors or
lie about the uses of their insured property).
183
See JERRY & RICHMOND, supra note 55, at 918 (explaining that liability coverage by defini-
tion is third-party coverage, meaning that it only pays for other people’s damages that the insured
driver caused); Wallace, supra note 7 (reporting that Uber’s liability policy did not cover a Houston
1130 Boston College Law Review [Vol. 56:1097
dents while searching for customers, they have no recompense for their own
injuries.
184
Accordingly, this Part argues that uberX drivers can hold Uber liable for
violating the UCL with its insurance misrepresentations.
185
Section A asserts
that California courts will treat an uberX driver suing Uber under the unfair-
ness prong of the UCL as a consumer rather than as a business competitor.
186
Section B then argues that Ubers insurance misrepresentations constitute an
unfair business practice within the meaning of the UCL, entitling uberX driv-
ers to restitution and injunctive relief.
187
A. To Use Is to Consume: Courts Should Consider uberX Drivers
Consumers Rather Than Business Competitors of Uber
If uberX drivers sue Uber alleging that its misleading insurance practices
are unfair under the UCL, California courts must first decide whether the ub-
erX drivers are consumers or business competitions within the meaning of the
UCL.
188
Courts should treat the drivers as consumers rather than competitors,
because their claims are not based on harm to the drivers’ business or competi-
tion generally.
189
Unlike the cell phone retailer that sued another cell phone
uberX driver’s medical bills and vehicle damage when he got in an accident because, as Uber ex-
plained, liability coverage only protects the driver from getting sued).
184
See Hourdajian, Insurance for uberX, supra note 8 (showing that during the time uberX driv-
ers are searching for fares, Uber does not provide uberX drivers with first-party coverage, such as
personal injury protection or collision or comprehensive coverage); Wallace, supra note 7 (reporting
that an injured Houston uberX driver had to pay for his own medical bills and vehicle damage after a
ride-sharing accident, though Uber offered to pay for his vehicle after the press got involved). To get
coverage for personal damages that may occur while trolling for fares, an uberX driver would need
first-party coverage, such as personal injury protection, comprehensive coverage, and/or collision
coverage. See J
ERRY & RICHMOND, supra note 55, at 918 (explaining first-party coverage, including
personal injury protection (which pays for the driver’s own medical expenses) and comprehensive and
collision coverages (which pay for damage to the driver’s own vehicle)). Absent such first-party cov-
erage, the only way an uberX driver could obtain compensation for his or her injuries during this peri-
od is if another driver with a liability policy struck the uberX driver. See id. (explaining how liability
coverage pays for third parties’ injuries).
185
See infra notes 188243 and accompanying text.
186
See infra notes 188198 and accompanying text.
187
See infra notes 199243 and accompanying text.
188
See Cel-Tech Commc’ns, Inc. v. L.A. Cellular Tel. Co., 973 P.2d 527, 54344 (Cal. 1999)
(determining that the plaintiff and defendant were direct competitors before analyzing whether the
defendant’s conduct was unfair under the new competitor standard of unfairness); Rankin v. Global
Tel*Link Corp., No. 13cv01117JCS, 2013 WL 3456949, at *16 (N.D. Cal. July 9, 2013) (deciding
that the plaintiff was a competitor, based on its allegations of monopolization, before analyzing
whether the defendant’s conduct was unfair under the competitor test). But see Drum v. San Fernando
Valley Bar Ass’n, 106 Cal. Rptr. 3d 46, 51, 54 (Cal. Ct. App. 2010) (refusing to decide whether the
plaintiff was a competitor or consumer, because under either standard of unfairness, the plaintiff failed
to state a UCL claim).
189
Compare Cel-Tech, 973 P.2d at 54446 (applying the competitor standard to the plaintiffs’
claim of unfair business practices because they alleged that the defendant’s below-market pricing
2015] Uber’s Insurance Coverage and Unfair Competition Laws 1131
retailer in the 1999 Supreme Court of California case Cel-Tech Communica-
tions, Inc. v. Los Angeles Cellular Telephone Co., an uberX driver is not direct-
ly competing with Uber for customers.
190
Further, an uberX driver would not
need to allege that Ubers practice harmed his or her ride-sharing business, as
the businesses owners alleged in Levitt v. Yelp! Inc., a 2014 decision rendered
by the U.S. Court of Appeals for the Ninth Circuit.
191
Although any of these
allegations would trigger the competitor standard of unfairness, none would
make sense in the context of an uberX driver’s action against Uber.
192
Instead, uberX drivers are likely to be considered consumers of Uber, be-
cause they use Ubers platform arrange ride-sharing transactions.
193
uberX driv-
scheme harmed competition), and Levitt v. Yelp! Inc., 765 F.3d 1123, 1136 (9th Cir. 2014) (applying
the competitor standard of unfairness to the plaintiffs’ claims even though they did not compete with
Yelp! because the “crux” of their case was that Yelp! injured their businesses and helped their com-
petitors), with Wilner v. Sunset Life Ins. Co., 93 Cal. Rptr. 2d 413, 42223 (Cal. Ct. App. 2000)
(treating the plaintiff as a consumer because she alleged that the defendant engaged in unfair sales
tactics to sell her a bad life insurance policy). Although plaintiffs can try to frame their cases as either
“competitor” or consumer” claims with their allegations, the courts ultimately decide which standard
to apply. See Levitt, 765 F.3d at 1136 (deciding to treat the plaintiffs as competitors); Rankin, 2013
WL 3456949, at *9, 1617 (deciding to treat the plaintiff as a competitor because the allegations in
the complaint were based on harm to competition rather than consumer injury, even though the plain-
tiff asked the court to apply the section 5 test for unfairness to consumer actions). Any uberX drivers
suing Uber over its insurance misrepresentations can likely avoid the strict competitor standard, as any
allegations arising from their injuries are unlikely to be related to antitrust or anticompetitive effects.
Cf. Cel-Tech, 973 P.2d at 54344 (adopting a narrow test for unfairness grounded in antitrust policy to
apply to competitor claims, and applying it to the plaintiff cell phone retailers who alleged that the
defendant’s sales tactics harmed competition).
190
Compare id. 53244 (noting that the plaintiffs and defendant were in direct competition with
one another, as they both sold cell phones), with Browning, supra note 24, at 84 (quoting Uber’s
statement that its drivers are really the transportation providers, and they use Uber’s platform to con-
duct business, whereas Uber is not a transportation carrier and does not provide transportation ser-
vices).
191
Compare Levitt, 765 F.3d at 1136 (treating the plaintiffs as competitors because they alleged
that Yelp!’s conduct hurt their businesses and helped their competitors), with McKell v. Wash. Mut.,
Inc., 49 Cal. Rptr. 3d 227, 241 (Cal. Ct. App. 2006) (treating the plaintiffs as consumers because they
alleged that the defendant overcharged them personally for underwriting services), and Wilner, 93
Cal. Rptr. 2d at 42223 (treating the plaintiffs as consumers because they alleged that the defendant
had a pattern of deceiving policyholders about their own life insurance policies).
192
Cf., e.g., Cel-Tech, 973 P.2d at 544 (applying the competitor standard of unfairness after the
plaintiffs alleged anticompetitive pricing); Levitt, 765 F.3d at 1136 (applying the competitor standard
of unfairness after the plaintiffs alleged harm to their businesses); Rankin, 2013 WL 3456949, at *16
(applying the competitor standard of unfairness after the plaintiffs alleged monopolization of the bail
bond industry). Moreover, neither uberX drivers nor taxicab drivers can make viable UCL allegations
against Uber based on anticompetitive conduct, because ride-sharing appears to have increased com-
petition within the transportation market. See O’Neil, supra note 25 (discussing how a few medallion
owners corned the Boston taxicab market and drove up prices; thus, they are angry that TNCs now
provide consumers with more options).
193
See Ehret v. Uber Tech., Inc., No. C140113, 2014 WL 4640170, at *10 (N.D. Cal. Sept. 17,
2014) (applying the consumer standard of unfairness to the Uber customer’s claim against Uber for
the fees she paid to Uber to use its service); Browning, supra note 24, at 84 (describing how mobile
phone apps like Uber merely facilitate ride-sharing between drivers and passengers); Nordman, supra
1132 Boston College Law Review [Vol. 56:1097
ers are users of the Uber ride-sharing platform, just like the Uber passenger
whom the U.S. District Court for the Northern District of California treated as a
consumer in 2014, in Ehret v. Uber Technologies, Inc.
194
uberX drivers are also
comparable to the life insurance policyholder whom the California Second Dis-
trict Court of Appeal treated as a consumer in 2000, in Wilner v. Sunset Life In-
surance Co.
195
Just as the Wilner plaintiff relied on her insurer’s misrepresenta-
tions about her life insurance, uberX drivers similarly rely on Uber for infor-
mation about their insurance coverage.
196
Further, the questionable employment
relationship between Uber and uberX drivers does not preclude application of
the consumer standard, as California’s Fourth District Court of Appeal demon-
strated in 2012, in Aleksick v. 7-Eleven, Inc.
197
Therefore, California courts
should treat uberX drivers suing Uber under the UCL as consumers.
198
note 13, at 6 (explaining how the Uber platform connects drivers with riders and takes a percentage of
drivers’ sales as a fee). Uber acknowledges that uberX drivers are more like users or partners of Uber.
See MacMillan, supra note 38 (quoting Uber’s founder as calling drivers his business partners); Ward,
supra note 47 (quoting an Uber representative stating that drivers conduct their business on the Uber
platform). When faced with a UCL lawsuit from uberX drivers, however, Uber may argue that the
drivers are more like business competitors by likening the uberX drivers using Uber’s platform to the
businesses using Yelp!’s platform in Levitt v. Yelp! Inc. in 2014 in the Ninth Circuit for the U.S. Court
of Appeals. See Levitt, 765 F.3d at 1136 (treating the plaintiff business owners as competitors even
though they compete with each other, not the defendant Yelp!).
194
See Ehret, 2014 WL 4640170, at *10 (treating Uber passenger as a consumer under the UCL
because she used the Uber app and paid Uber the fee it tacked onto her fare); K
OOPMAN ET AL., supra
note 23, at 4 & n.4 (noting that the sharing economy is a marketplace where peers come together to
exchange goods and services, and citing Uber as an example); Nordman, supra note 13, at 6 (explain-
ing how Uber lets ride-sharing drivers use its platform in exchange for a percentage of drivers’ sales).
195
See Wilner, 93 Cal. Rptr. 2d at 42223 (treating the life insurance policyholder as a consumer
under the UCL and finding the insurer’s practice unfair).
196
See id. (noting that the plaintiff challenged the insurer’s practice of selling life insurance poli-
cies to new customers without informing them that the policies are deliberately underfunded and not
suitable for most people); Bensinger & Bhuiyan, supra note 38 (reporting that many uberX drivers are
inexperienced with the transportation market and thus rely on Uber for insurance information);
Rassman, supra note 10, at 90 (explaining how Uber fails to educate drivers about their potential gaps
in insurance coverage). Uber’s and Lyft’s websites provide information about ride-sharing drivers’
insurance coverage, but do not advise drivers to talk to their personal insurers about coverage. See
Hourdajian, Eliminating Ridesharing Ambiguity, supra note 6 (providing information about Uber’s
insurance); Hourdajian, Insurance for uberX, supra note 8 (providing information about Uber’s insur-
ance); We Go the Extra Mile for Safety, supra note 50 (providing information about Lyft’s insurance);
cf. Fernholz, supra note 47 (reporting that an anonymous Uber representative stated that the drivers
are responsible for determining whether their personal auto insurance will cover their ride-sharing
activities); NAIC Consumer Alert for Ridesharing Drivers, supra note 8 (advising drivers to talk to
their personal auto insurers before driving for a TNC).
197
See Aleksick, 140 Cal. Rptr. 3d. at 798, 80708 (treating the franchise employee as a consumer
of the franchisor company, which was not her direct employer); Huet, Sharing Economy Workers
Injured on the Job, supra note 41 (questioning whether Uber misclassifies its drivers as independent
contractors rather than employees). Although the issue of whether uberX drivers are employees or
independent contractors remains unsettled, that classification would not change the court’s consumer-
competitor analysis because employees and non-employees can be consumers under the UCL. See
Aleksick, 140 Cal. Rptr. 3d. at 806, 808 n.6 (treating the plaintiff as a consumer of the 7-Eleven fran-
2015] Uber’s Insurance Coverage and Unfair Competition Laws 1133
B. Tipping the Scale: Uber’s Insurance Misrepresentations Fail the
Balancing Test for Unfairness and Violate the UCL
After a California court determines that an uberX driver challenging Ub-
ers insurance representations should be considered a consumer under the
UCL, the court must decide which test for unfair business practices to apply
and whether Uber’s conduct satisfies that test.
199
Subsection 1 urges California
courts to apply the balancing test to consumer UCL lawsuits, including any
potential suit brought by an uberX driver against Uber.
200
Subsection 2 then
applies the balancing test to an uberX drivers potential allegations, arguing
that Uber’s insurance misrepresentations constitute an unfair business practice,
which entitles uberX drivers to relief.
201
1. Courts Should Apply the Balancing Test to Consumer UCL Actions
Courts should apply the balancing test for unfair business practices to ub-
erX driversUCL claims against Uber because case law supports the balancing
tests continued use in consumer lawsuits, and the test effectuates the sweeping
purpose of the UCL.
202
Although the Supreme Court of California has not dic-
tated the standard for unfair business practices that courts should apply to con-
sumer claims, it has declined three times to overrule the balancing test.
203
First,
chisor even though she was not its employee, and hinting that her employer, the local franchise owner,
could be liable to employees under the UCL); Epstein, supra note 41(discussing two class action law-
suits against Uber pending in California that challenge Uber’s classification of uberX drivers as inde-
pendent contractors). See generally Michelle L. Evans, Who Is a “Consumer” Entitled to Protection
of State Deceptive Trade Practice and Consumer Protection Acts, 63 A.L.R. 5th 9097, 11931
(1998) (providing an overview of cases in which parties were deemed consumers for the purposes of
state unfair competition laws, including cases in which employees and equipment operators were
considered consumers).
198
See, e.g., Ehret, 2014 WL 4640170, at *10 (treating the Uber passenger as a consumer); Ale-
ksick, 140 Cal. Rptr. 3d at 798, 807 (treating the franchise employee as a consumer); Wilner, 93 Cal.
Rptr. 2d at 423 (treating the policyholder as a consumer).
199
See Camacho v. Auto. Club of S. Cal., 48 Cal. Rptr. 3d 770, 77379 (Cal. Ct. App. 2006)
(stating that the test for unfair business practices in consumer actions is uncertain, analyzing the three
different possible tests, choosing the “section 5 test,” and applying it to the defendant’s practices).
200
See infra notes 202218 and accompanying text.
201
See infra notes 219243 and accompanying text.
202
See Progressive W. Ins. Co. v. Yolo Cnty. Superior Court, 37 Cal. Rptr. 3d 434, 453 (Cal. Ct.
App. 2006) (concluding that the balancing test should still apply in consumer UCL actions because (1)
Cel-Tech did not explicitly overrule it, (2) the Supreme Court of California has not overruled it in the
six years since Cel-Tech, and (3) courts should construe unfairness broadly to fulfill the legislative
intent of protecting vulnerable consumers). The balancing test holds that a business practice is unfair
“if it violates established public policy or if it is immoral, unethical, oppressive or unscrupulous and
causes injury to consumers which outweighs its benefits.” McKell, 49 Cal. Rptr. 3d at 240.
203
See Rose v. Bank of Am., 304 P.3d 181, 187 n.9 (Cal. 2013), cert. denied, 134 S. Ct. 2870
(2014) (refusing to decide which standard for unfairness to apply in a consumer UCL claim because
the parties did not fully brief the issue); Zhang v. Superior Court, 304 P.3d 163, 174 n.9 (Cal. 2013)
(confirming that the standard for unfair business practices in consumer UCL lawsuits remains unset-
1134 Boston College Law Review [Vol. 56:1097
when the Supreme Court of California held in Cel-Tech that the balancing test
no longer applies, it restricted this holding to competitor lawsuits.
204
The Cel-
Tech court explicitly stated, albeit in dicta, that nothing in its UCL discussion
pertained to consumer actions.
205
Then, in 2014, in Zhang v. Superior Court, the Supreme Court of Califor-
nia implied that courts may continue to apply the balancing test to consum-
ers.
206
The court stated in Zhang that the issue of which test to apply in the
consumer context remains unsettled.
207
Finally, in an opinion issued that same
day in 2014, in Rose v. Bank of America, the Supreme Court of California re-
fused to decide which test for unfairness to apply in consumer UCL law-
suits.
208
Because Californias highest court has not expressly overruled use of
the balancing test in consumer actions, lower courts should continue to apply it
in that context.
209
Furthermore, the balancing test serves the broad protective goals underly-
ing the UCL better than the alternative tests.
210
The legislature intended for the
tled); Cel-Tech, 973 P.2d at 544 n.12 (leaving open the issue of which test for unfairness should apply
to consumer UCL lawsuits); see also Smith v. State Farm Mut. Auto. Ins. Co., 113 Cal. Rptr. 2d 399,
416 n.23 (Cal. Ct. App. 2001) (reading Cel-Tech as supporting the continued use of the balancing test
to determine unfairness in the consumer context).
204
See Cel-Tech, 973 P.2d at 544 (adopting a new test for unfairness in the competitor context
after deeming the balancing test too vague for businesses because it does not provide courts or busi-
nesses with any meaningful guidance about what type of conduct the UCL prohibits).
205
Id. at 544 n.12 (“This case involves an action by a competitor alleging anticompetitive practic-
es. Our discussion and this test are limited to that context. Nothing we say relates to actions by con-
sumers . . . We also express no view on . . . federal cases . . . that involve injury to consumers . . . .”).
206
See Zhang, 304 P.3d at 174 n.9 (stating that despite the different tests for unfairness being used,
the court would not address the issue).
207
Id. (stating that “[t]he standard for determining what business acts or practices are ‘unfair’ in
consumer actions under the UCL is currently unsettled . . . . The parties here do not address this ques-
tion, nor do we.”) The court cited cases that alternatively use the revised Cel-Tech test, the section 5
test, and balancing test in support of its contention. See id.
208
Rose, 304 P.3d at 187 n.9 (“The Court of Appeal identified three separate tests for [the plain-
tiff’s claim of] ‘unfairness’ under the UCL, and applied all three of them. Plaintiffs assert in cursory
fashion that the court misapplied one of these tests. We decline to address this claim, which is neither
properly raised nor sufficiently briefed.”).
209
See Lozano v. AT&T Wireless Servs., Inc., 504 F.3d 718, 736 (9th Cir. 2007) (stating that
even though Cel-Tech disapproves of the balancing test for competitors, courts can continue to apply
it to consumers in the absence of clear guidance from the Supreme Court of California as to which test
should apply); Donohue v. Apple, Inc., 871 F. Supp. 2d 913, 928 (N.D. Cal. 2012) (refusing to apply
the section 5 test and instead continuing to apply the balancing test because the Supreme Court of
California has not approved the section 5 test); Progressive, 37 Cal. Rptr. 3d at 453 (applying the
balancing test because it comports with case law and the consumer protection goals of the UCL).
210
See Barquis v. Merchs. Collection Ass’n, 496 P.2d 817, 830 (Cal. 1972) (finding that, given
the creativity of unethical businesses, the legislature intended for courts to have the power in equity to
enjoin each original scheme; thus, the standard for unfairness under the UCL must be broad). The
alternative tests for unfair business practices that California courts apply, in lieu of the balancing test,
are the section 5 test and the revised Cel-Tech test. See Camacho, 48 Cal. Rptr. 3d at 77677 (estab-
lishing the section 5 test, which states that a business practice is unfair if the consumer suffered a
2015] Uber’s Insurance Coverage and Unfair Competition Laws 1135
UCL to protect all of societynot just individual customersfrom businesses
acting unethically and unfairly.
211
To that end, the standard for unfairness to
consumers must be flexible enough to allow courts to intervene whenever
businesses contrive new, unanticipated schemes.
212
The balancing test is suffi-
ciently malleable to achieve this goal, as it allows courts to take many counter-
vailing factors into account.
213
In contrast, the alternative tests undermine the purpose of the UCL by re-
ducing consumer ability to challenge newly invented unfair business schemes.
214
First, the section 5 test for unfair business practices is inappropriate for consum-
er actions, because it is derived from a federal statute, the Federal Trade Com-
mission Act (“FTCA”), which does not serve the same purpose as the UCL.
215
substantial, unavoidable injury that is not outweighed by benefits to other consumers or competition in
general); Gregory v. Albertson’s, Inc., 128 Cal. Rptr. 2d 389, 395 (Cal. Ct. App. 2002) (establishing
the revised Cel-Tech test, which holds that a business practice is unfair if it violates a written public
policy that is established by law).
211
See Arkin, supra note 56, at 157 (describing the broad scope of the UCL, despite passage of
Proposition 64 narrowing the standing rules to require injury in fact). California’s UCL provides only
equitable relief, and not damages for individual plaintiffs, because it is intended to prevent further
harm from befalling the public. See Barquis, 496 P.2d at 830 (discussing the court’s equitable power
to enjoin any business scheme that seems facially unjust); 2004 Cal. Legis. Serv. Prop. 64 (West)
(codified as amended at C
AL. BUS. & PROF. CODE §§ 17203, 17204, 17206, 17535, 17536 (West 2012))
(stating that the public’s intent in passing Proposition 64 was to prevent frivolous UCL lawsuits but
retain the right of private individuals to sue to protect the consuming public).
212
See Nat’l Rural Telecommc’n Coop. v. DIRECTV, Inc., 319 F. Supp. 2d 1059, 1075 (C.D.
Cal. 2003) (explaining that the statutory term “unfair” is defined broadly to give courts the maximum
amount of discretion to deal with harmful business schemes); Cel-Tech, 973 P.2d at 540 & n.9 (ex-
plaining that the drafters of the UCL could not anticipate precisely all of the unfair business schemes
that would arise in the future, so they drafted the UCL using “sweeping” language on purpose and
have continually expanded the UCL’s reach); Camacho, 48 Cal. Rptr. 3d at 776 (stating that requiring
plaintiffs to tether allegations of unfairness to a specific legislative provision conflicts with the goals
of the UCL, as it limits courts’ abilities to strike down unfair practices). Consumers require greater
protection from unfair business practices than business competitors, as consumers are constantly un-
der pressure from businesses to buy their goods and services. See Barquis, 496 P.2d at 829 (referring
to the psychological pressure of advertising); Progressive, 37 Cal. Rptr. 3d at 453 (stating that the
balancing test protects vulnerable consumers from “sharp practices”).
213
See, e.g., Ehret, 2014 WL 4640170, at *10 (balancing Uber’s lack of justification for its de-
ceptive fees against the customer’s overpayment to find that the customer stated a claim against Ub-
er); McKell, 49 Cal. Rptr. 3d at 24041 (balancing the homeowners’ overpayment of underwriting
fees against the mortgage lender’s motivations, in light of the federal policy favoring home ownership,
to find that the homeowners stated a UCL claim against the lender); Progressive, 37 Cal. Rptr. 3d at
441, 453 (balancing the plaintiff’s economic injuries against the insurer’s lack of justification for its
reimbursement and finding that the plaintiff’s claim against his insurer could proceed).
214
Cel-Tech, 973 P.2d at 540.
215
See Federal Trade Commission Act, 15 U.S.C. § 45(a)(1) (2012) (prohibiting “[u]nfair meth-
ods of competition in or affecting commerce, and unfair or deceptive acts or practices in or affecting
commerce”); C
AL. BUS. & PROF. CODE § 17200 (West 2012) (prohibiting “any unlawful, unfair or
fraudulent business act or practice and unfair, deceptive, untrue or misleading advertising”); Lozano,
504 F.3d at 736 (rejecting the section 5 test for consumer UCL actions, reasoning it inappropriate to
apply the Federal Trade Commission Act (“FTCA”)’s definition of “unfair” to consumer actions);
Cel-Tech, 973 P.2d at 54344 (stating that although the FTCA and California UCL have similar pur-
1136 Boston College Law Review [Vol. 56:1097
The FTCA empowers the Federal Trade Commission to act to preserve competi-
tion within markets, which is not necessarily the concern of private citizens su-
ing under the UCL for redress.
216
Likewise, the revised Cel-Tech test for unfair-
ness is improper because it is too restrictive; it bars many consumer UCL actions
that the legislature did not intend to block.
217
Therefore, only the balancing test
affords courts the latitude they need to accomplish the UCLs sweeping goals.
218
poses, the statutes are enforced very differently); Camacho, 48 Cal. Rptr. 3d at 77677 (deriving the
“section 5 test” from the FTCA because Cel-Tech looked to the FTCA for guidance) (citing Federal
Trade Commission Act § 5(n), 15 U.S.C. § 45(n)). In 2007, in Lozano v. AT&T Wireless Services,
Inc., the U.S. Court of Appeals for the Ninth Circuit held that courts facing consumer UCL claims
should not copy Cel-Tech’s method of looking to the FTCA for guidance. See 504 F.3d at 736. This is
because Cel-Tech was concerned only with anticompetitive conduct. See id.; Cel-Tech, 973 P.2d at
544 nn.1112 (noting that the court’s discussion of federal law pertained only to competitor lawsuits
under the FTCA and UCL and, therefore, the discussion did not relate to consumer UCL actions).
216
Compare 15 U.S.C. § 45(a)(2) (empowering the Federal Trade Commission (“FTC”) to en-
force the FTCA), and H.R. Rep. No. 103-138), at 24 (1993) (stating the purpose of the FTCA and
the FTC’s broad authority to declare practices unfair), and Averitt, supra note 102, at 22829 (ex-
plaining the six categories of conduct that violated the FTCA as it existed in 1980, all of which in-
volved anticompetitive conduct and/or antitrust law), with C
AL. BUS. & PROF. CODE § 17204 (allow-
ing any person that has suffered an economic injury as a result of a prohibited practice to bring suit),
and Barquis, 496 P.2d at 829 (holding that the UCL not only prohibits anticompetitive practices
among business competitors, but it also protects vulnerable consumers), and Arkin, supra note 94, at
157 (explaining that the goal of the UCL is broader than just protecting business competitors; it aims
to protect all of society). The California UCL and FTCA have many differences, including: the UCL’s
broader standing provisions; the UCL’s five theories of liability, compared to the FTCA’s two; the
UCL’s longer statute of limitations; and the FTCA’s exemption for insurance companies. See Lenore
Albert & Michael Thurman, Unfair and Deceptive Practices: A Comparison of the FTC Act and Cali-
fornia’s UCL, 22 C
OMPETITION: J. ANTITRUST & UNFAIR COMPETITION L. SEC. ST. B. CAL. 51, 60
61, 67–68 (2013).
217
See Graham v. Bank of Am., N.A., 172 Cal. Rptr. 3d 218, 233 (2014) (laying out the revised
Cel-Tech test, which states that conduct is unfair if it violates a public policy that is “tethered to spe-
cific constitutional, statutory or regulatory provisions”) (internal quotation marks omitted); see, e.g.,
Aleksick, 140 Cal. Rptr. 3d at 80708 (using the revised Cel-Tech test to dismiss the franchise em-
ployee’s complaint against the franchisor for its payroll practices); Scripps v. Superior Court, 134 Cal.
Rptr. 2d 101, 105, 11617 (Cal. Ct. App. 2003) (using the revised Cel-Tech test to dismiss the pa-
tients’ claim against their clinic for refusing to treat them after they sued for malpractice); Gregory,
128 Cal. Rptr. 2d at 395 (using the revised Cel-Tech test to dismiss the citizen’s complaint against the
grocery store chain for leaving its store unoccupied). If California’s Fourth District Court of Appeal
had evaluated the employee’s claim under the balancing test (rather than the revised Cel-Tech test) in
Aleksick v. 7-Eleven, Inc. it may have allowed the claim to proceed, as the franchisor’s payroll prac-
tice seemed to undermine California’s fair labor policies and Labor Code. See Aleksick, 140 Cal. Rptr.
3d at 798, 808 (explaining 7-Eleven’s challenged business practice, whereby the franchisor requires
its franchises to calculate payroll in a way that shorts employees’ wages, and invoking California’s
wage statute); McKell, 49 Cal. Rptr. 3d at 240 (stating that any business practice that “violates estab-
lished public policy” is unfair).
218
Compare McKell, 49 Cal. Rptr. 3d at 240 (describing how the balancing test takes into account
established public policies, consumer harm, societal benefits, defendant motivations, and more), with
Camacho, 48 Cal. Rptr. 3d at 777 (dismissing concerns that the section 5 test, which imposes a re-
quirement that plaintiffs must suffer substantial injury to bring a claim under the unfair prong of the
UCL, further limits standing), and Graham, 172 Cal. Rptr. 3d at 233 (acknowledging that the revised
Cel-Tech test for unfairness is more rigorous than the balancing test and section 5 test), and Wilson v.
2015] Uber’s Insurance Coverage and Unfair Competition Laws 1137
2. Applying the Balancing Test to Uber’s Insurance Misrepresentations,
Courts Should Deem uberX Drivers Entitled to Relief
Applying the balancing test for unfairness to Ubers misrepresentations
about ride-sharing insurance coverage, Ubers practices should be found to vio-
late the UCL.
219
The test holds that a business practice is unfairif it violates
established public policy or if it is immoral, unethical, oppressive or unscrupu-
lous and causes injury to consumers which outweighs its benefits.
220
Ubers
practice satisfies this standard of unfairness in multiple ways.
221
Accordingly,
injured uberX drivers are entitled to restitution and injunctive relief from Ub-
er.
222
First, Ubers misrepresentations about uberX drivers inadequate insur-
ance coverage violate established public policy.
223
Uber misrepresents that ub-
Hynek, 144 Cal. Rptr. 3d 4, 11 (Cal. Ct. App. 2002) (stating that the revised Cel-Tech test is signifi-
cantly narrower than the balancing test); see also Arkin, supra note 94, at 157 (explaining the broad
scope of the UCL).
219
See Ehret, 2014 WL 4640170, at *10 (applying the balancing test to determine that Uber’s
misleading gratuity scheme is arguably unfair and allowing the plaintiff’s claim to survive a motion to
dismiss); NAIC Consumer Alert for Ridesharing Drivers, supra note 8 (warning ride-sharing drivers
that they may have gaps in their insurance coverage, as commercial activity voids most personal poli-
cies); Hourdajian, Eliminating Ridesharing Ambiguity, supra note 6 (stating that Uber’s contingent
liability coverage fills the insurance gap between when an uberX driver becomes available or hire and
when he or she accepts a ride request). Unfairness is a question of fact for the judge or jury to decide
on a case-by-case basis. Countrywide Fin. Corp. v. Bundy, 113 Cal. Rptr. 3d 705, 723 (Cal. Ct. App.
2010).
220
McKell, 49 Cal. Rptr. 3d at 240.
221
See id. (stating the factors to consider when applying the balancing test); Bensinger & Bhui-
yan, supra note 38 (stating that Uber representatives told potential uberX drivers at a recruiting event
that they do not need commercial insurance, and then told reporters that many personal policies will
cover drivers during the trolling period); Hourdajian, Eliminating Ridesharing Ambiguity, supra note
6 (telling uberX drivers that they should be confident that they no longer have gaps in their insurance
coverage while ride-sharing); cf. Packel, Lyft, Uber Ridesharing Bids, supra note 11 (reporting that
Pennsylvania insurers opine that Uber’s contingent liability policy, offered to drivers during the
trolling period, does not fix the ride-sharing insurance problem).
222
See Cel-Tech, 973 P.2d at 539 (explaining that private plaintiffs’ remedies under the UCL are
limited to restitution and injunctive relief). This Part assumes that uberX drivers have standing. Cf.
Kwikset Corp. v. Superior Court, 246 P.3d 877, 885, 887 (Cal. 2011) (noting that to have standing to
sue under the UCL’s unfairness prong, the plaintiff must demonstrate an economic injury in fact caused
by actual reliance on the defendant’s misrepresentations, which are at the core of the claim). This Part
also assumes that state law does not explicitly sanction Uber’s conduct, as a law proclaiming Uber’s
insurance scheme legal could provide Uber with immunity. Cf. Cel-Tech, 973 P.2d at 541 (explaining
that if a law sanctions a business practice, it serves as a safe harbor for defendants accused of unfair
competition). Because ride-sharing and TNCs are new to the transportation market, it is unlikely that
states have laws explicitly sanctioning Uber’s insurance scheme. See Browning, supra note 24, at 85
(explaining that the emergence of ride-sharing has raised new questions about applicable regulations
and insurance).
223
See Packel, Lyft, Uber Ridesharing Bids, supra note 11 (reporting the Insurance Federation of
Pennsylvania’s harsh criticism of Uber’s inadequate insurance coverage and education for ride-
sharing drivers).
1138 Boston College Law Review [Vol. 56:1097
erX drivers are fully covered while they drive around searching for fares,
which violates state policies favoring first-party insurance coverage.
224
Ubers
misrepresentations are similar to those made by the defendant mortgage lender
in 2006, in McKell v. Washington Mutual, Inc., a case in California’s Second
District Court of Appeal.
225
The lender in McKell undermined federal policy
aimed at reducing the cost of homeownership by misrepresenting the cost of
underwriting.
226
Similarly, the remaining gaps in Ubers insurance coverage
for uberX drivers undermine state efforts to ensure drivers receive compensa-
tion for their own injuries.
227
Ubers misleading uberX drivers about the ap-
plicability of their personal policies and failing to provide them with personal
injury, comprehensive, collision, or uninsured motorist protection frustrates the
purpose of these local laws.
228
224
See Hourdajian, Insurance for uberX, supra note 8 (providing an overview of Uber’s insur-
ance for uberX drivers, which lacks first-party coverage for drivers while they are driving around
searching for fares); Summary of State Laws Related to Auto Insurance, supra note 65 (indicating that
seventeen states require drivers to carry personal injury protection and thirty-five require drivers to
carry uninsured motorist coverage); Notice to Transportation Network Company Drivers, supra note 8
(advising ride-sharing drivers to consider buying a commercial liability policy with personal injury
protection, comprehensive, collision, and uninsured motorist coverages to ensure that they are person-
ally protected). Recall that first-party coverage compensates the insured for personal losses, such as
personal injury protection and collision coverage. J
ERRY & RICHMOND, supra note 55, at 918.
225
Compare McKell, 49 Cal. Rptr. 3d at 235, 241 (explaining how the mortgage lender over-
charged homeowners for automated underwriting, in violation of federal public policy aimed at mak-
ing homeownership more affordable), with Hourdajian, Eliminating Ridesharing Ambiguity, supra
note 6 (making inaccurate statements to the public about uberX drivers’ insurance coverage while they
are in between fares, specifically that “the vast majority of personal insurance policies cover [the
trolling] period either by the plain terms of the insurance policy, or due to the insurance requirements
set by state”), and Friedhoff, supra note 44 (reporting that the insurance industry says that commercial
activities, such as driving around searching for fares, are not covered by personal policies).
226
McKell, 49 Cal. Rptr. 3d at 24041.
227
Compare McKell, 49 Cal. Rptr. 3d at 24041 (explaining how the lender’s activity under-
mined federal policy), and Jerry & Richmond, supra note 55, at 8990, 9798 (describing states’
rationale for regulating auto insurance and imposing first-party coverage requirements), and Summary
of State Laws Related to Auto Insurance, supra note 65(demonstrating that the majority of states man-
date some kind of first-party coverage), with Hourdajian, Eliminating Ridesharing Ambiguity, supra
note 6 (telling uberX drivers that they should feel confident that they have sufficient insurance cover-
age, despite the fact that drivers have no first party coverages in place while they drive around search-
ing for fares).
228
See Hourdajian, Insurance for uberX, supra note 8 (showing that uberX drivers are covered by
Uber’s contingent liability policy during the trolling period, but not showing personal injury protec-
tion, uninsured motorist coverage, or collision and comprehensive coverage); Notice to Transporta-
tion Network Company Drivers, supra note 8 (advising ride-sharing drivers to buy commercial insur-
ance and/or first-party coverages); Packel, Lyft, Uber Ridesharing Bids, supra note 11 (noting that
Uber’s insurance scheme fails to meet the Insurance Federation of Pennsylvania’s standards, and that
offering merely contingent liability coverage in between rides will create confusion and delay during
the claims process).
2015] Uber’s Insurance Coverage and Unfair Competition Laws 1139
Second, Ubers knowingly misleading uberX drivers about their inade-
quate insurance constitutes immoral, unethical, and unscrupulous conduct.
229
Similar to the Wilner insurer who engaged in unethical and unfair conduct by
knowingly selling unsuitable life insurance policies to customers, Uber knows
that most uberX drivers personal policies prohibit commercial activity.
230
Ub-
er also knows that its contingent liability policy will not compensate the uberX
driver for any of his or her own injuries, as the Wilner insurer knew that it was
selling underfunded policies.
231
Furthermore, just like it was unscrupulous for
the insurer in Progressive West Insurance Co. v. Yolo County Superior Court in
2005 in California’s Third District Court of Appeal to demand repayments to
which it was not entitled, Uber similarly disregards the law.
232
Uber unscrupu-
lously encourages uberX drivers to submit claims to their personal insurer first
for accidents that occur during the trolling period, despite the fact that personal
policies do not cover commercial activity.
233
229
See Progressive, 37 Cal. Rptr. 3d at 453 (finding that the insurer’s practice of demanding
reimbursement from payees without regard to legality seemed immoral and unethical); Wilner, 93 Cal.
Rptr. 2d at 42223 (holding that the insurer’s knowingly selling inappropriate and unsuitable life
insurance policies to consumers was obviously “immoral, unethical and unscrupulous,” and therefore
unfair). Compare Hourdajian, Insurance for uberX, supra note 8 (suggesting that uberX drivers’ per-
sonal policies will cover them while they are in between ride-sharing trips), with Packel, Lyft, Uber
Ridesharing Bids, supra note 11 (claiming that Uber knows that uberX drivers’ personal auto insur-
ance will not cover any sort of commercial activity, leaving drivers exposed).
230
Compare Wilner, 93 Cal. Rptr. 2d at 422 (noting that the insurer tried to sell inappropriate life
insurance policies to new customers, knowing that the policies were inferior and probably not in the
best interests of the customers), with Fernholz, supra note 47 (reporting that an Uber representative
stated that drivers know their personal policies may not apply), and NAIC Consumer Alert for Rides-
haring Drivers, supra note 8 (warning uberX drivers that most personal auto policies contain livery
exclusions), and Packel, Lyft, Uber Ridesharing Bids, supra note 11 (claiming that Uber knows about
the remaining gaps in uberX drivers’ personal auto insurance).
231
Compare Wilner, 93 Cal. Rptr. 2d at 423 (noting that the insurer knew that the policies were
deliberately underfunded but failed to tell the policyholders), with Wallace, supra note 7 (reporting
that an Uber representative stated that liability insurance only protects uberX drivers from third-party
lawsuits and does not compensate drivers for their injuries). Uber clearly knows the value of first-
party coverages, as it provides uberX drivers with uninsured motorist coverage, contingent and colli-
sion coverage, and personal injury protection while they are on a ride-sharing trip. See Hourdajian,
Insurance for uberX, supra note 8 (explaining the commercial insurance coverage that Uber provides
for uberX drivers beginning when they accept a ride request).
232
Compare Progressive, 37 Cal. Rptr. 3d at 286 (noting that the insurer’s practice of demanding
repayment from policyholders for any money it pays out, without regard to common law doctrines
limiting the insurer’s legal entitlement to such money, was unscrupulous), with Hourdajian, Insurance
for uberX, supra note 8 (explaining that the contingent liability coverage for uberX drivers only ap-
plies if the uberX driver’s personal insurer denies the claim or pays nothing).
233
See Friedhoff, supra note 44 (reporting that driving around searching for fares is a commercial
activity not covered by personal policies); Huet, Rideshare Drivers Cornered into Secrecy, supra note
54 (reporting that some uberX drivers feel pressured to lie to their insurers about engaging in ride-
sharing to avoid losing their personal policies, which may constitute insurance fraud); Hourdajian,
Insurance for uberX, supra note 8 (implying that uberX drivers must submit claims to their personal
insurers for accidents that occur while they are driving around searching for fares).
1140 Boston College Law Review [Vol. 56:1097
Moreover, Ubers misrepresentations to uberX drivers about insurance
coverage do not provide a public benefit that outweighs the harm to drivers.
234
An uberX driver that gets into an accident while searching for fares may incur
injuries in the form of medical bills, vehicle repair costs, and lost wages.
235
Uber cannot provide a proper justification for its insurance scheme that out-
weighs this harm, just as in Ehret, where Uber failed to justify its misleading
fee structure that harmed passengers.
236
Ubers insurance misrepresentations
arguably produce a public benefit, in that more drivers may have signed up to
provide transportation services through uberX because they do note realize
their insurance exposure.
237
This benefit of having more uberX vehicles on the
road, however, does not outweigh the potential economic and bodily harm to
uberX drivers.
238
Therefore, Uber providing misinformation about uberX driv-
ers insurance coverage while they troll for fares constitutes an unfair business
practice.
239
If California courts deem Ubers insurance misrepresentations to be an
unfair business practice within the meaning of the UCL, injured uberX drivers
234
See McKell, 49 Cal. Rptr. 3d at 240 (stating that if the harm to consumers outweighs the bene-
fit of the business practice, it is unfair under the UCL); Hourdajian, Insurance for uberX, supra note 8
(outlining uberX drivers’ insurance coverage).
235
See Catherine Clifford, Good News for Airbnb Hosts and Uber Drivers: Here Comes Insur-
ance, E
NTREPRENEUR (Dec. 5, 2014), http://www.entrepreneur.com/article/240540 archived at http://
perma.cc/A7ZP-V5KJ (noting that ride-sharing drivers who get into accidents may lose a lot of in-
come while their cars are being repaired); Wallace, supra note 7 (reporting that a Houston Uber driver
who was in an automobile accident had to pay for his own medical bills and vehicle repairs, although
Uber offered to pay for the vehicle damage after the press got involved).
236
See Ehret, 2014 WL 4640170, at *10 (allowing the Uber customer’s UCL claim to proceed
because Uber had not yet provided a justification for its misleading fees).
237
See Badger, Now We Know, supra note 36 (reporting that Uber’s fleet of drivers doubles every
six months); Bensinger & Bhuiyan, supra note 38 (reporting that most uberX drivers are relatively
inexperienced with the transportation market and rely on Uber for information); Hourdajian, supra
note 6 (reassuring uberX drivers that they should be confident that no insurance gaps exist); O’Neil,
supra note 25 (noting that the influx of Uber drivers disrupted the Boston taxicab market, to the bene-
fit of consumers).
238
Cf. JERRY & RICHMOND, supra note 55, at 9799, 92425 (describing the lengths state legisla-
tures go through to ensure that all drivers have adequate insurance coverage, including mandating
liability coverage and setting up residual markets through which high-risk individuals can purchase
insurance); NAIC
WHITE PAPER ON TNC INSURANCE, supra note 8, at 812 (explaining the risks and
costs associated with ride-sharing, despite TNCs arguments that ride-sharing increases road safety by
reducing the number of personal vehicles on the road).
239
See McKell, 49 Cal. Rptr. 3d at 240 (stating that under the balancing test for unfairness, if the
harm to consumers outweighs the benefit of the business practice, it is unfair under the UCL). Com-
pare NAIC Consumer Alert for Ridesharing Drivers, supra note 8 (warning ride-sharing drivers about
remaining gaps in their insurance coverage, including the fact that most personal policies contain
livery exclusions), and Rassman, supra note 10, at 90 (quoting the Insurance Federation of Pennsyl-
vania’s opinion that Uber’s offering only contingent liability coverage during the trolling period
leaves drivers exposed), with Hourdajian, Eliminating Ridesharing Ambiguity, supra note 6 (trying to
recruit new uberX drivers with representations that any gaps in ride-sharing drivers’ insurance cover-
age no longer exist)
2015] Uber’s Insurance Coverage and Unfair Competition Laws 1141
would be entitled to restitution and injunctive relief.
240
As such, uberX drivers
should receive restitution to compensate them for any economic losses they
incurred as a result of Uber’s misleading them about their insurance coverage
during the trolling period.
241
Further, uberX drivers should seek an injunction
to enjoin Uber from continuing to operate uberX without disclosing to drivers
the truth about their insurance gaps.
242
Such injunctive relief would prevent
Uber from continuing to mislead uberX drivers, thus fulfilling the UCLs broad
goal of protecting the public from any and all unfair business schemes.
243
C
ONCLUSION
As ride-sharing services such as uberX gain popularity, courts are seeing
an influx of disputes over insurance coverage for uberX drivers. uberX drivers
lack adequate insurance coverage during the time period when they have the
Uber app on but do not yet have a passenger. This is due in part to Uber mis-
leading uberX drivers about the type and amount of insurance coverage availa-
ble to them. Based on these misrepresentations, injured uberX drivers should
be able to sue Uber under Californias unfair competition law for engaging in
unfair business practices. In such a lawsuit, California courts will likely treat
an uberX driver as a consumer rather than a business competitor of Uber. Fur-
ther, courts should apply the flexible balancing test to determine whether Ub-
er’s practice is unfair, as this test best serves the broad protective intent under-
lying the UCL. Applying this balancing test to Ubers insurance misrepresenta-
tions, courts should find Ubers practice unfair and grant injured uberX drivers
restitution and injunctive relief. Accordingly, ride-sharing drivers should try to
hold transportation network companies accountable for their statements. If Ub-
240
See CAL. BUS. & PROF. CODE §§ 17200, 17203 (prohibiting unfair business practices and
providing that anyone who is injured by such practices can seek injunctive relief); Cel-Tech, 973 P.2d at
539 (stating that successful plaintiffs are entitled to restitution under the UCL as well).
241
See Cel-Tech, 973 P.2d at 539 (indicating that UCL plaintiffs can obtain restitution); Clifford,
supra note 235 (describing how ride-sharing drivers may suffer lost wages if involved in an automo-
bile accident); Wallace, supra note 7 (discussing Uber driver who incurred medical bills and vehicle
repair costs after accident); see also NAIC Consumer Alert for Ridesharing Drivers, supra note 8
(warning drivers that their personal auto policies may not cover them once they make themselves
available for hire through a TNC app).
242
See CAL. BUS. & PROF. CODE § 17203 (stating that businesses that engage or propose to engage
in unfair business practices can be enjoined); Packel, Lyft, Uber Ridesharing Bids, supra note 11 (stat-
ing the Pennsylvania insurers opine that Uber needs more insurance coverage and better insurance educa-
tion for ride-sharing drivers); see also C
AL. PUB. UTIL. CODE § 5432 (West Supp. 2015) (requiring
Uber to disclose to ride-sharing drivers, starting in July 2015, that their personal policies will not cover
use of their vehicles in connection with a TNC).
243
See Barquis, 496 P.2d at 83031 (describing the “sweeping” language of the UCL, which
empowers courts to invalidate any and all business practices that are facially unfair and dishonest);
Arkin, supra note 94, at 157 (explaining that the broad purpose of the UCL is to protect all of society
from the harm caused by unfair and unscrupulous business practices, not just business competitors).
1142 Boston College Law Review [Vol. 56:1097
er truly is all about sharing, it should share the responsibility for the risks it
creates by putting ride-sharing drivers on the road.
J
ENNIE DAV I S