www.policyschool.ca
PUBLICATIONS
PUBLICATIONS
SPP Research Paper
SPP Research Paper
Volume 15:7 February 2022
http://dx.doi.org/10.11575/sppp.v15i1.73545
A PROPOSAL FOR A “BIG BANG”
CORPORATE TAX REFORM
Jack Mintz
SUMMARY
To put it in simple terms, Canada’s corporate income tax is a mess. It discourages
capital investment most heavily in many service sectors, is highly distortionary
and overwhelmingly complex, impeding economic growth. With current inflation
rates, these distortions are even larger. With so many tax preferences, the
combined federal-provincial corporate income tax with a headline tax rate of 26
percent raises revenue little more than 19 percent of corporate profits.
To build up productive capacity in a post-COVID world, a big-bang approach
is needed to put Canada into a better position to attract investment and
reduce distortions in the business tax system. There are some major revenue-
neutral reforms that could improve neutrality and simplify the overly complex
corporate tax. Here, we particularly explore a corporate tax on distributed
profits without a reduction in corporate tax revenues.
A distributed profits approach means profits from investment activities would
only be taxed when they are distributed to investors. This allows profits
reinvested in capital to be exempt from taxation. A good example of this design
is Estonia’s corporate profit tax on distributions, introduced in 2000. This
reform resulted in the elimination of the corporate tax on reinvested profits —
these profits are only taxed when the profits are distributed. In 1999, prior to
the reform, corporate taxes, as a share of taxes, made up 0.9 per cent of GDP.
In 2019, they made up 1.7 per cent of GDP. Estonia has also had remarkable
investment performance since with fixed capital formation equal to 27 percent
of GDP compared to 23 percent in Canada since 2015.
I wish to thank the editor, Ken McKenzie, Jerey Trossman and two anonymous reviews for detailed comments that significantly
improved the paper. Special thanks to Phil Bazel who helped with underlying research.
1
Taxes generally distort economic activity — production of the taxed good or service
is reduced when eective tax rates are increased. The value of the lost production is
greater than the value of the tax added to government revenue. This results in several
distortions: intertemporal, inter-industry, inter-asset, international, risk-taking, financing
and business organization. The corporate tax on distributed profits, while still having
some disadvantages, does have several advantages in reducing these distortions.
The proposal considered here would tax deemed distributions of profits including share
buybacks and certain deemed payments to prevent erosion of the tax base. Passive
income and capital gains earned by the corporation would remain taxed similar to
existing rules. The revenue-neutral corporate tax on distributed profits would be an
estimated 16 per cent at the federal level and 11.2 per cent on a provincial average tax
rate, when brought forward to the 2022/23 fiscal year results in the same corporate
tax revenues collected as in 2022 ($37 billion). While it seems that a distributed tax
that exempts reinvested profits would lower the corporate taxable income, it actually
doesn’t lower it much. Due to tax incentives, taxable corporate income ($370 billion for
2022/23) is significantly below corporate operating profits ($515 billion). The distributed
tax removes the need for tax incentives, no longer providing those tax savings.
This proposed model is not perfect, but it is better than the current system, which is
distortionary, with high economic, compliance and administrative costs. A distributed
profits design would make the corporate income tax fairer and simpler, reducing
administrative and compliance costs, while not significantly eroding corporate tax
revenues.
2
In the 2020 Tax Competitiveness report (Bazel and Mintz 2021), we concluded that
Canada’s corporate tax system is attractive to encourage investment in marginal
projects, although it has become much more distortionary and non-neutral due to
incentives, thereby undermining the productive use of resources. It has a relatively high
corporate income tax rate compared to most advanced countries, making Canada less
attractive for lumpy greenfield projects with high economic rents from intangible or
resource investments.
In this paper, I look at possible major revenue-neutral reforms to the corporate income
tax with the aim to improve neutrality and simplify the system. Canada could further
pursue its corporate tax reforms by lowering tax rates and broadening tax bases to
reflect economic income. However, this approach to reform, which has been the focus
for Canada since 1985, seems to have reached its limit in reducing corporate income
tax rates due to political opposition to corporate tax reduction, which is not unusual.
1
Instead, a fundamental tax reform could help tilt the playing field towards Canada to
boost investment, reduce tax distortions and simplify administration and compliance,
without a loss in revenue. I call this a big-bang reform. The basic proposal is to convert
the corporate tax into a tax on distributed profits that would improve static and
dynamic eciency in the corporate tax system.
2
It is not a perfect system, but it could
be a practical approach to boost growth and make the corporate tax more ecient
and fairer.
There are some important advantages to the approach, particularly reducing tax
distortions that discourage investment, especially for the service sectors in the
economy. The proposed structure would also be compatible with international tax
systems, even under the proposed global corporate minimum tax, and continue
support for small businesses. It does have one disadvantage — it would potentially be
distortionary in financing decisions by favouring retained earnings over other funding
sources. Recommendations will be made to the taxation of share buybacks, corporate
passive income and capital gains that would create potentially greater neutrality among
financing sources compared to the existing system.
The paper begins with a discussion of the problems with the corporate income tax
in Canada. This will be followed by a description of the proposed corporate tax on
distributed profits, including a review of both the positive and negative aspects of
the proposal. A rent-based approach to the taxation of corporate distributions is
considered, which would be consistent with a personal tax reform along the lines of
the expenditure tax approach.
1
In 1997, I had access to unpublished poll results showing that Canadians then believed that corporations
do not pay enough taxes as they do today. Similarly, Gallup reports that roughly 70 per cent of Americans
believe corporations pay too little tax. The Gallup opinion poll is quite stable no matter the state of the
economy between the years 2004 and 2019. About 63 per cent believe high-income taxpayers do not pay
enough in 2019, similar to 2004. About 43 per cent believe the middle class pays too much in 2019, which is
about the same as 2004. See https://news.gallup.com/poll/1714/taxes.aspx.
2
Our proposal could also be adjusted to tax only corporate rents by redefining the tax base as distributed
profits net of the new equity financing (although this would require a substantially higher corporate income
tax rate to make up for the loss of revenues). This approach would be appropriate if the personal income tax
is also reformed to remove the tax on savings. We will discuss this further below.
3
WHY IS THERE A CORPORATE TAX AND WHY IS IT FAILING IN
ACHIEVING ITS PURPOSE?
The corporate income tax plays an important role in financing federal and provincial
government public services. It raises close to $100 billion, almost 10 per cent of
consolidated general government revenues (Statistics Canada 2021). Despite its
importance, questions have been raised as to whether it should be abolished.
3
It has
been criticized as being the economically costliest tax, hurting growth and productivity
the most (Dahlby and Ferede 2018). It has also attracted criticism for being unfair by
being passed on by corporations as higher prices charged to consumers (Baker et al.
2020) or by reducing employment and wages paid to workers (McKenzie and Ferede
2018). To the extent that the corporate tax falls on returns to shareholders, its incidence
still falls not just on high-income investors, but also many middle and low-income
households, including worker pension plans.
Why do we have a corporate income tax? The principle for corporate tax design
in Canada, and most countries in the world, is based on the notion of taxing
comprehensive income for both personal and corporate income tax purposes.
Comprehensive income includes annual income from labour and capital net of
expenses to earn income. It includes employment compensation, business income,
property or investment income (dividends, interest and rents) and capital gains. In
principle, comprehensive income is adjusted for inflation and measured net of any
losses in business and capital income (if the tax base is negative, a refund should be
paid equal to the tax rate multiplied by the loss).
In principle, the corporate tax is not needed if profits are attributed to shareholders
for personal income and withholding tax purposes, similar to partnership income.
This is administratively complex with tiers of corporate ownership, as well as requiring
investors to pay tax on income that has not yet been distributed.
4
Alternatively, a
government could tax accrued capital gains from the change in the market value
of assets each year rather than realized capital gains upon the disposal of assets.
However, this forces owners to sell assets if they have insucient liquidity, as well
as being dicult to administer in the case of non-traded assets with no observable
market value. Further, non-resident shareowners would be out of reach for capital gains
taxation since they are only taxed by their resident governments.
As pointed out by the Carter Report (Government of Canada 1966), the corporate
tax may have two purposes. First, the corporate tax is a backstop to the personal tax
by operating as a withholding tax — the profit tax would be refunded once income
3
For example, L. Kotliko, “Abolish the Corporate Income Tax,” New York Times, January 5, 2014. See also E.
Dolan, “The Progressive Case for Abolishing the Corporate Income Tax,” 2017, https://www.milkenreview.org/
articles/the-progressive-case-for-abolishing-the-corporate-income-tax-2.
4
As noted by a Congressional Research Report in the United States: “One integration approach would be
to eliminate the corporate tax and allocate earnings directly to shareholders in a manner similar to which
partnerships … allocate income to their partners and shareholders” (Keightley and Sherlock 2014).
4
is distributed to investors.
5
Second, the corporate income tax withholds profits from
foreign investors who might also credit Canadian tax against their foreign tax liabilities,
resulting in a transfer of revenue from foreign to Canadian treasuries without a loss
of investment. The Technical Committee on Business Taxation (1997) further argued
that the corporate tax is a surrogate “benefit” tax when governments provide public
services such as infrastructure and limited liability laws that enhance the profitability of
corporations in the absence of user fees to recover the cost of public provision.
In recent years, the tension between the domestic and international roles for the
company tax has played a significant role in corporate tax policy developments. With
greater global capital mobility since 1990 and the erosion of corporate tax crediting,
6
countries have reduced corporate income tax rates and broadened corporate tax
bases to attract investment, improve tax eciency and keep profits in their jurisdiction.
For international competitive reasons, Canada has lowered its combined federal
and corporate income tax rate from 43 per cent in 2000 to 26 per cent by 2012
while curbing, to some degree, accelerated depreciation, investment tax credits and
other tax preferences.
7
This brought Canada’s corporate income tax rate in line with
other countries, rather than being the highest among OECD countries in 2000. The
consequence, however, was that the corporate tax rate fell below the top personal rate,
reducing the withholding role of the corporate income tax.
8
As Finance Canada has
observed, a portion of the personal income tax base shifted to the corporate sector
to reduce personal tax payments that would be subject to much higher tax rates
(Government of Canada 2015). Currently, the average top federal-provincial personal
income tax rate is roughly 52 per cent.
9
While these arguments for corporate taxation are well known, they are a basis
for suggesting a few principles for corporate tax design. Insofar as corporate tax
discourages economic activity, it should be designed to discourage as little economic
activity as possible, and so impose the lowest possible cost on the economy. Only in
5
The withholding role could imply that the corporate tax should be applied to economic rents, especially
if consistent with the personal tax (Institute of Fiscal Studies (Meade Report) 1978; Mirrlees Report 2011).
Some argue for the corporate tax to be applied to economic rents even if personal income continues to be
taxed at the personal level (Boadway and Tremblay 2014; McKenzie and Smart 2019). We will return to these
arguments below.
6
The crediting argument lost some appeal as countries moved away from taxing dividends paid by foreign
aliates to their parents. Crediting still applies to branch income, passive income, non-treaty income and,
under U.S. law, global intangible low-income tax (GILTI) income. Further, recent global discussions that would
result in countries agreeing to impose a minimum corporate income tax at the rate of 15 per cent would
reinstate the importance of the crediting argument.
7
After 2012, Canada corporate income tax changed modestly until 2018 when it introduced temporary
accelerated depreciation in response to U.S. tax reform (that reduced the U.S. corporate rate somewhat
below Canada’s (Bazel and Mintz 2019).
8
Top corporate and personal income tax rates were roughly aligned in the previous decade. In 1999, the top
personal income tax and corporate income tax rates were almost equal (46 and 45 per cent respectively).
Back in 1987, the top personal income tax rate was 51 per cent and the top corporate income tax rate was
about 52 per cent.
9
Tax preferences also result in corporate tax payments as a share of profits dropping below the statutory rate.
Further, small Canadian-controlled private corporations are taxed at preferential rates at about a combined
federal-provincial rate of 12.5 per cent (Mintz, Smith and Venkatachalam 2021).
5
the presence of a market failure would deviations from neutrality be desirable, such
as taxing pollution or subsidizing research, given the inability for innovators to fully
appropriate returns. However, even in the case of market failures, it is still necessary
to demonstrate that a tax policy is better to correct for market failures compared to
other interventionist tools, such as subsidies or regulations. For example, research
can be supported by grants instead of tax credits and pollution can be corrected by
regulations instead of taxes. Evaluating the benefits and costs of specific tax deviations
from neutrality compared to other forms of public intervention goes beyond the focus
of this paper. However, one can achieve corporate tax neutrality and correct market
failures with more suitable public policies.
AN EVALUATION OF THE EXISTING CORPORATE INCOME TAX
It is one thing to design a perfect corporate income tax, but it is another to achieve
perfection given other political and institutional considerations. Nonetheless, it is
worthwhile to evaluate the existing corporate income tax in terms of its impact on
tax policy considerations with respect to economic eciency, equity and cost of
compliance and administration (Mintz 2018). These tax structure considerations are
important to consider in setting tax policy.
ECONOMIC EFFICIENCY
Taxes generally distort economic activity. They reduce the production of the taxed
good or service, including capital and labour services, with the quantum of reduction
determined by the elasticity of supply and demand for such goods or services.
The value of this lost production will be greater than the value of the tax added to
government revenue. These eciency considerations are broken down into several
types of distortions.
Intertemporal Distortion
The corporate tax discourages investment and the capacity to produce goods and
services for future domestic consumption and exports (dynamic ineciency). It creates
a wedge between the pre-tax return and after-tax return on capital. The larger (smaller)
the wedge, the less (more) capital will be employed by businesses. Assuming the full
phasing out of accelerated depreciation (that begins in 2023), the existing corporate
income tax imposes a wedge equal to 19.5 per cent between pre- and post-tax rates
of return of capital with a higher wedge for services (e.g., communications at 22.1 per
cent) compared to manufacturing and forestry (13.7 per cent) (Table 1).
Inter-industry and Inter-asset Distortions
Distortions in the corporate tax system result in a suboptimal use of capital in the
economy as capital is allocated to business activities with lower marginal economic
6
returns due to tax preferences.
10
Static eciency is illustrated by the dierentiation
in inter-industry and inter-asset eective tax rates on marginal investments (METR
11
).
As shown in Table 1, the variation is quite significant, even with the phasing out of
accelerated depreciation. Since 2015, Canada’s static ineciency has more than doubled
(Bazel and Mintz 2019). The eciency cost can be approximated as a dispersion index
(the weighted standard deviation of METRs per dollar of marginal tax revenue (Bazel
and Mintz 2019). The overall dispersion index in 2020 is 7.2 per cent, with the inter-asset
dispersion equal to 2.9 per cent and inter-industry dispersion equal to 1.5 per cent. Thus,
inter-asset distortions are more important than the inter-industry distortions.
Table 1. Federal-Provincial METRs by Industry and Province 2020
Note: Assumes accelerated depreciation is fully phased out. METRs measure corporate income taxes,
sales taxes on capital purchases, real estate transfer taxes and other relevant capital taxes as a share of
corporate profits earned on a marginal investment.
International Distortions
From a national perspective, a corporate tax in Canada could distort export and import
capital flows, in part depending on relative corporate tax rates elsewhere, assuming all
other economic factors are the same. The corporate tax encourages businesses to shift
their investment to lower-taxed foreign jurisdictions, leading to a loss of income and
employment in the Canadian economy. It also discourages foreign investors from lower
taxed jurisdictions to fund Canadian operations. A high corporate income tax incents
companies to shift profits to low-tax jurisdictions by booking expenses in Canada and
under-pricing goods and services sold to foreign aliates (transfer pricing). To that
end, the corporate tax should bear in mind the relationship of Canada’s corporate
10
Baquee and Farhi (2020) find that the static ineciency in the allocation of capital reduces productivity
by 15 per cent. Similarly, Da-Rocha, Mendes Tavaremal and Retuccia (2020) find that misallocation due to
dierential taxes on establishments causes substantial productivity losses — one-half due to the static eect
and the other half to a dynamic eect.
11
The marginal eective tax rate (METR) is explained in Bazel and Mintz 2021. Briefly, it is the amount of
corporate income tax, capital taxes, transfer taxes and sales taxes on capital purchases paid as a share of
corporate profits for marginal investments — those investments that earn sucient profit to cover the cost of
equity and debt financing.
7
income tax with that of other jurisdictions, while also considering international capital
flow distortions.
12
Including accelerated depreciation, Canada’s current METR on
manufacturing and services of 15.6 per cent is below those of the U.S., Europe, G7,
G20, OECD and 94-country averages, but our corporate income tax rate of 26.2 per
cent is higher than the U.S. (25.7 per cent), Europe (23.6 per cent) and the 94-country
weighted average (25.4 per cent) (Bazel and Mintz 2021).
13
New rules to limit interest
deductions for foreign companies operating in Canada and the minimum tax applied
by foreign countries on the income earned by their resident companies operating in
Canada could result in foreign-owned investments bearing a higher burden on capital
compared to domestic-owned investments.
Risk-taking Distortions
The corporate tax discourages risk taking by taxing the profits earned but not sharing
the losses incurred by investors (Mintz 1988). If profits and losses were treated
symmetrically under the income tax system, a government would be acting as a silent
partner in sharing risks. Given the lack of full refundability, non-risky investments
are tax-preferred and startup companies are less able to compete with profitable
incumbent firms in a market.
14
A simple example is the following: Suppose the expected return on farming is five per
cent: a 50 per cent chance of sucient rain so that a 15 per cent rate of return is earned
and a 50 per cent chance of a drought with a negative five per cent rate of return (the
expected return is sum of the probability times the rate of return in each state). If the
corporate income tax rate is 25 per cent and there is no refundability of losses, the
rate of return with sucient rain falls from 15 per cent to 11.25 per cent (the five per
cent loss in the drought remains the same since the government does not share the
loss). The after-tax expected return falls from five per cent to 3.13 per cent, implying an
eective tax rate of 37.4 per cent instead of 25 per cent.
One could adopt the full refundability of corporate tax losses and tax credits, at
least in principle, but this comes with three potential costs. The first would be a
shift of expenses into the corporate sector from personal tax to take advantage of
refundability that is not provided generally under the personal income tax. Second,
a corporate tax would make Canada a dumping ground for losses from abroad as
12
The OECD Base Erosion and Profit Shifting studies are reducing some of the international distortions but
cannot completely do so. Only a world of equal eective tax rates among all countries would achieve global
capital allocation neutrality.
13
The U.K. has announced it is increasing its corporate income tax in 2023 from 19 to 25 per cent (to be slightly
below the Canadian tax rate) and the Biden administration will be pushing for a higher corporate income tax
rate in the U.S.
14
Under Canadian tax law, some refundability is provided, but not full refundability. A company can carry back
operating losses for three years and claim a refund of past taxes paid for three years. It can carry forward
operating losses for 20 years to reduce operating profits in future years, although amounts are not indexed
for either inflation or borrowing interest rates. Capital losses can be carried back three years or forward
indefinitely but written o only against capital gains. Some taxable losses or credits are refundable, such as
research and development tax credits for Canadian-controlled private corporations and flow-through shares
of oil, gas and mining companies that renounce deductions in favour of investors who claim the deduction
under their personal income tax.
8
other countries do not provide full refundability for losses. Third, as found with the full
refundability of the research and development scientific credit in the early 1980s, tax
evasion could arise, such as investors moving to other countries after cashing refunds
without carrying out activities. Thus, one cannot expect limits on refundability resulting
in higher taxes on risky activities.
Financing Distortions
In the absence of taxation, corporations will fund capital expenditures with retained
earnings, new equity issues or debt. Retained earnings may be preferred since a
company uses internal resources rather than having to issue securities at a higher cost
to outside investors who have less knowledge about the firm. Debt is preferable to
lenders if they have a first claim to assets should the firm go bankrupt. New equity
issues attract a wider market of owners. Each financing source has its beneficial
economic attribute.
Since interest expense is deductible from corporate income (subject to certain
limitations), debt financing is encouraged compared to retained earnings and new
equity issue financing (Mintz 1995). However, interest paid to individual investors is fully
taxed under the personal income tax while dividends and capital gains are preferentially
taxed in recognition of the profits, prior to their distribution or reinvestment in the
company, having already been subject to one level of tax.
15
This can be seen in Table 2
with respect to taxes paid on income derived from a large Ontario corporation.
Table 2. Tax on Various Sources of Income Derived from a Large Ontario
Corporation (2021)
Dividend Paid to
Canadian Investor
Reinvested
Earnings
Profit Paid out as Deductible Expense (e.g., interest,
royalties, employment income)
Corporate Profits $100.00 $100.00 $100.00
Corporate Tax $26.50 $26.50 $0
Net Profit $73.50 $73.50 $100.00
Personal Tax (1) $28.91 $19.67 $53.47
Net Income $44.59 $53.83 $46.53
(1) Assumes the investor is the high-income investor. Dividend tax rate (39.34 per cent) includes the
dividend tax credit for eligible dividends. It is assumed capital gains tax rate of 26.76 per cent applies on
the gain realized in the same year.
Table 2 assumes corporate profits are taxed at the combined statutory federal-Ontario
rate of 26.5 per cent. The marginal investor for the Ontario company resides in Ontario,
paying a tax rate of 39.34 per cent on distributed profits (taking into account the
dividend tax credit). Reinvested earnings increase the value of the firm, dollar for dollar,
and, assuming the shares are disposed in the current year, are subject to capital gains
tax (only half of capital gains is taxed). Interest and other deductible charges paid out
as income to the investor are fully taxed.
15
If it is assumed that a dollar of retained earnings is invested in the firm’s capital, it increases the value of the
firm by one dollar. The capital gain for shareowners is subject to tax when the shareowner sells interests in
the company.
9
Given the relatively low capital gains tax rate, reinvested earnings are the least costly
form of finance from a tax perspective in this example. The combined corporate and
personal tax rate on reinvested earnings is 42.17 per cent. On bond interest and other
deductible charges, the tax rate is 53.47 per cent and on dividends, 55.41 per cent
(thereby discouraging new equity issues the most).
The financing distortions, however, are much more complicated than shown here:
The corporate tax rate varies by size of business (a 13.5 per cent tax rate is
applied to the first $500,000 profits earned by Canadian-controlled private
corporations in Ontario). This increases the attractiveness of retained earnings
as a source of finance. The concessionary rate is clawed back when passive
income is more than $50,000;
With tax incentives, the average tax rate (corporate income taxes as a share of
corporate profits) is lower than the general statutory tax rate. For example, in
the 2016 taxation year, the average federal corporate tax rate on net financial
income was 7.9 per cent
16
even though the statutory tax rate was 15 per cent.
This lower eective tax rate makes retained earnings and new equity issues
even more attractive since the dividend tax credit and concessionary capital
gains tax rate are based on a notional profit tax rate of 26.5 per cent;
The lack of inflation adjustments results in the overstatement of profits
when depreciation and inventory valuation is based on historical rather than
replacement prices (even at an annual two per cent inflation, historical values
from 20 years ago are roughly two-thirds of today’s prices). However, interest
expenses, unadjusted for inflation, favour debt finance, which is becoming
even more important today with recent inflation rates after 2020;
The investor often holds shares for a longer period than one year. If so, the
capital gains tax, which only applies to realizations, is deferred until the shares
are sold. Although interest rates are low these days, the deferral advantage
reduces the eective tax rate on capital gains. On the other hand, the lack of
full refundability for capital losses and inflation increases the eective capital
gains tax rate on real income;
Pension plans do not pay tax on dividends, interest or capital gains but their
income derived from corporations is subject to corporate income tax. For
pension plans, debt finance (and other deductible charges such as royalties
and rents) is preferable to avoid corporate tax payments;
Dividends and interest paid to non-residents are subject to Canadian
withholding tax (most interest is exempt from withholding tax by treaty).
Capital gains as well as interest and dividends are subject to corporate or
personal income tax in foreign jurisdictions (with a credit for withholding
taxes). Overall, the tax paid by foreign investors varies from zero to the top
income tax rate in the country. Debt is often preferable if foreign investors pay
little tax on Canadian investments.
16
Based on the latest year available from the Canada Revenue Agency: https://www.canada.ca/content/dam/
cra-arc/prog-policy/stats/t2-corp-stats/2012-2016/t2-crp-sttstcs-tbl10-e.pdf.
10
The choice of financing decisions, therefore, depends on relevant corporate and
personal income tax rates. The marginal source comes from investors who would be
indierent between equity and bond assets (Miller 1977). This implies that the marginal
investor would be taxed on income at equal eective tax rates on equity and bonds,
accounting for both corporate and personal taxes. Assuming binding constraints
limiting short selling of securities, other investors would only hold debt or equity
depending on their personal tax rates. Using Millers example, suppose the marginal
investor is not taxed on capital gains and dividends at the personal level but fully taxed
on interest. This would imply that the marginal investor holding Ontario stocks would
have a personal tax rate on interest equal to 26.5 per cent (those with higher personal
tax rates would only buy equity and those with lower tax rates would buy only bonds).
17
In a global context, the story becomes far more complicated since there are many
corporate income tax rates, as well as personal income tax rates.
18
An Ontario
corporation would have a lower corporate tax rate than one in Japan, which is currently
30.6 per cent. A Japanese corporation would have an incentive to invest in the Ontario
corporation’s equity, financing it with debt borrowed in Japan. An international capital
market equilibrium would result in the international marginal investor being indierent
between Japanese equity and bonds with the Ontario corporation being fully equity
financed by the Japanese corporation. Using the Miller assumption of a zero tax on
equity, the international investors would hold Japanese debt facing a tax rate of 30.6
per cent with higher income taxpayers buying Japanese or Canadian equity and low-
income taxpayers buying Japanese bonds (since the Canadian company would not
issue bonds).
Obviously, Japanese corporations would be unable to own all global corporate equity
in the world. Most important, companies do not go to the extreme of all debt or all
equity finance since they are trading o tax benefits with other economic factors,
such as default costs, signalling costs and use of tax losses (Mintz 1995). Complicated
international tax structures encourage indirect financing structures to take advantage
of interest, leasing and general administrative write-os for tax purposes (Mintz
and Weichenrieder 2010). The main point is that the simple case in Table 2 is not
representative. The financial decisions depend on the interaction of corporate and
personal taxes globally with corporate policies selecting clienteles to hold their
securities. A key conclusion is that countries with higher corporate income tax rates
like Canada would attract more debt finance in global markets, even if an international
marginal investor is indierent between Canadian and other international securities.
17
For indierence, the Miller equilibrium generally implies that u+ t(1-u) = m with u= corporate income tax rate,
t= personal income tax rate on equity and m = personal income tax rate on debt. With retained earnings
finance, in Ontario, u=.265 and t=.2675 and so u+t(1-u) = .426. The combined tax rate on equity income is
equal to the tax on bond finance when m = 42.6 per cent.
18
This discussion follows some very early work when I looked at multiple corporate income tax rates such
as the case of dierential corporate income tax rates on manufacturing and non-manufacturing profits
(Bartholdy, Fisher and Mintz 1987). See also Mintz and Weichenrieder (2010), chapter 3, comparing the eect
of corporate and personal taxes on financing decisions for parents, subsidiaries and conduit entities.
11
Business Organizational Distortions
Distortions also arise with respect to the organization of businesses, which can be done
in corporate or non-corporate forms, such as sole proprietorships, unlimited or limited
liability partnerships or trusts. When alternative vehicles receive better income tax
treatment than corporations, those businesses that are carried on in corporate form
for economic reasons suer a competitive tax disadvantage that distorts investment
and production.
19
The existing corporate tax system encourages the formation of
corporations compared to sole proprietorships and partnerships whose owners earn
income that is subject to a higher income tax rate.
Prior to October 31, 2006, trusts had been favourably treated since they could
distribute income to avoid payment of corporate tax with the distributions taxed
favourably as dividends (Mintz and Richardson 2006). With income trusts becoming
taxable as specialized flow-through income trusts (SIFTs) in 2006, the incentive to
reorganize companies as income trusts only remains for real estate investment trusts.
EQUITY
A major concern in corporate taxation is horizontal equity, the equal treatment
of taxpayers with similar resources under the tax system. Non-neutrality creates
unfairness where one segment of taxpayers carrying on a business activity are taxed
more favourably than another segment of taxpayers carrying on that same business
activity. This occurs, for example, with dierential corporate tax rates for dierent
sectors, with corporations, with dierent corporate tax rates for dierent types of
ownership or by use of more favourably taxed business vehicles.
As well, corporate taxation can be viewed by some as raising questions about
vertical equity, whereby taxes paid will vary according to ability to pay. For example,
corporations and their shareholders are paying at a lower tax rate than other
businesses or individuals who have lower incomes. As discussed above, the eect of
corporate tax on vertical equity is not straightforward. If corporate taxes fall on labour
income or on consumers through higher prices charged for goods and services, it
can be regressive. If it falls on capital, it will impact higher income Canadians more
heavily, but it will also reduce pension plan returns and those lower and middle-income
Canadians who own equity. The point is that the corporate tax is a clumsy way to
achieve redistribution through the tax system.
19
Goolsbee (1997) estimates the economic cost associated with organizational distortions is relatively small,
accounting for 10 to 20 per cent of corporate tax revenues.
12
COMPLEXITY AND ADMINISTRABILITY
The corporate income tax is often criticized for its high level of structural and legislative
complexity, resulting in high compliance costs for taxpayers and administrative costs
for governments. Complexity arises from various sources:
(i) Complex business arrangements that make it dicult to determine profit;
(ii) Policies that require a line to be drawn between targeted and non-targeted
activities, such as manufacturing, small business, clean energy and research and
development;
(iii) Constant changes to the corporate tax base and structure that require
transitional arrangements;
(iv) International flows of capital and income that require special rules to
determine profits subject to tax.
No doubt the corporate income tax is complex, particularly in the areas of
intercorporate and international activities. It is unrealistic to think that a corporate
income tax system will ever be simple, although some forms of taxation can reduce
compliance and administrative costs compared to others.
To conclude, the strongest arguments made for corporate taxation is with respect to
its neutrality to ensure it operates as a backstop to the personal tax, withholds income
(or rents) accruing to non-residents and performs, when needed, as an ecient benefit
tax. However, the existing system is failing at achieving these roles at a significant
economic cost.
WHY A “BIG-BANG” CORPORATE TAX REFORM TODAY?
Three economic reasons can be given for a big-bang corporate tax reform:
1. To rejuvenate private sector investment in Canada by reducing the intertemporal
distortion that would improve labour productivity, encourage the adoption of
new technologies and grow the Canadian economy;
2. To reduce inter-asset and inter-industry distortions in the corporate tax to
ensure capital is allocated to the best economic use;
3. To simplify the corporate tax system.
While Canada could pursue a strategy to improve the existing corporate income tax by
achieving greater neutrality, it is unlikely to deal with many distortions, in some cases
due to inherent diculties to avoid them, such as inflation, financing distortions and
risk taking. A new approach to corporate taxation would spur investment and improve
the allocation of capital resources.
Much has been written about corporate tax design. As discussed in detail above, the
Carter Report (1966) made a classic argument for a corporate income tax based on
comprehensive income. In later years, several important studies have argued in favour
13
of expenditure taxation, which would imply a tax on economic rents, the latter being
the surplus of income in excess of the opportunity costs of using capital, labour and
other inputs in production. The rent approach is discussed in the final section.
A third approach is a tax on distributed profits. One can view this as a deferral
approach to corporate taxation whereby profits from investment activities are only
taxed when they are distributed to investors, implying that profits reinvested in capital
are exempt from taxation (an exception would apply to passive income that would
be taxed at the corporate level). Deferral taxation has been used in various contexts
in the past. In many companies, foreign profits of subsidiaries have been taxed when
distributed to the parent company (and still prevails in some cases today). In Chile,
reinvested corporate profits have been taxed at lower rates compared to distributed
profits up until 2017.
The deferral approach is also used for capital gains taxation. Realized capital gains are
taxed only upon disposal and, in selected cases like venture capital or real estate, could
be deferred further if an investment is rolled over into another qualifying investment.
Realized capital gains may also be deferred for share exchanges when companies are
merged. The deferral of tax can result in much lower eective tax rates on capital.
However, with negative or low real interest rates in recent years, deferral is not as
beneficial as it once was.
The reason countries adopt such provisions is to reduce the ineciency of taxing
realized capital gains. A capital gains tax on disposals causes a locked-in eect
whereby an investor would rather hold a less well-performing asset for a longer period
rather than buy more profitable investments. Thus, rollovers remove a tax barrier to
readjust investment portfolios. A deferral approach for the corporate tax could also
have a positive impact on investments by enabling companies to postpone corporate
taxation if profits are reinvested in new capital projects for economic gain.
While Chile has disbanded its favourable taxation of retained earnings, some new
countries have adopted a corporate tax on distributed profits in recent years. Here, we
pay particular attention to Estonia’s corporate income tax.
ESTONIA’S CORPORATE PROFIT TAX ON DISTRIBUTIONS
In 2000, Estonia introduced a unique approach to corporate taxation applied to all
companies operating in Estonia (also adopted by Latvia in 2018). Instead of applying
tax to profits, only corporate distributions (dividends and other deemed amounts)
are taxed. The Estonian corporate tax exempts profits from active business income,
passive (investment) income and capital gains from the sale of assets. However, when
the profits are distributed to residents or non-residents, whether earned domestically
or internationally, they are subject to a 20 per cent tax
20
with further personal
tax on residents or withholding tax on non-residents. Distributed profits include
dividends, share buybacks, capital reductions, liquidation proceeds and deemed profit
20
The tax rate on dividends is equal to 20/80 or 25 per cent to be equivalent to the corporate rate of 20 per
cent on distributed dividends.
14
distributions. In principle, profit and loss accounting under the Estonian tax is irrelevant
since all profit distributions are taxed, even if the distribution is more than profits.
Although a country could levy a personal income tax rate higher than the corporate
income tax, Estonia has made its tax simpler by adopting a flat personal income tax
rate on residents at 20 per cent. Distributions are exempt at the personal level since
they have already been subject to the corporate tax.
Estonian companies are taxed on their worldwide income. However, with dividends
paid from profits received as dividends or branch income from other residents, the EU
and foreign entities with a minimum 10 per cent ownership are exempt from Estonian
corporate tax to avoid double taxation. Dividend income received from low-tax
countries or tax havens is deemed to be distributions when passed on to investors.
As of 2018, the tax rate was reduced to 14 per cent on distributions that are less than
the average of the past three years. However, such distributions are subject to a special
withholding tax of seven per cent on residents and non-residents (unless reduced by
treaty for non-residents to five per cent or zero).
Deemed dividend amounts include fringe benefits, donations, non-business expenses
and certain payments paid to entities in tax havens. Loans to shareholders may be
deemed to be hidden profit distributions. Stock dividends (share bonuses) are exempt
from the corporate tax. Gifts and donations made to certain qualifying recipients are
only subject to corporate tax if expenses exceed three per cent of the social tax base
for the existing year or10 per cent of the profit of the last financial year according to
statutory financial statements. Latvia also includes bad debts, excess interest payments
and transfer pricing adjustments as part of deemed amounts.
The result of the Estonian reform is to eliminate the corporate tax on reinvested profits.
Such profits would be taxed when the profits are eventually distributed. The profits are
defined as book profits with no adjustments for accelerated depreciation and loss carry
forwards/backs. Estonia eschews tax credits given its exemption for reinvested profits.
Among other policies, including a flat personal income tax, tax reform has made
Estonia quite attractive for investment. As we show in Bazel and Mintz (2021), it
had a 31 per cent increase in investment from 2015 to 2019 but overall growth has
picked up since its initial reform. Although not many studies have been published,
there is evidence the Estonian approach has contributed to a more robust business
sector. One of the few careful studies was done by Maso, Meriküll and Vahter (2011).
It shows that Estonian companies held more liquid assets and reduced debt after
the reform, enabling them to better withstand the 2008 financial crisis. They also
found improvement in both investment and labour productivity using a dierence-in-
dierence econometric approach that compares Estonia to other Baltic states.
Since 1999, corporate tax revenues in Estonia have increased fivefold from 105 to 509
million euros in 2019. As a share of taxes, corporate taxes made up 5.5 per cent of
revenues in 2019 (1.7 percent of GDP), compared to six per cent in 1999 (0,9 percent of
GDP), prior to the adoption of the new corporate tax system. In other words, there has
not been little erosion in corporate tax revenues.
15
The OECD discussions on base erosion and profit shifting has led to an agreement for
countries to impose a 15 per cent corporate tax rate on the profits earned by foreign
aliates of resident multinationals. Special provisions apply to those countries with
eligible distribution tax regimes whereby deemed distribution taxes would be included
as part of covered taxes to calculate the tax paid in the host country (OECD 2021).
A CORPORATE TAX ON DISTRIBUTED PROFITS FOR CANADA
Here, we look specifically at the corporate distribution tax to minimize tax distortions
and improve the investment climate. The basic elements of the tax on distributed
profits are proposed as follows:
The corporate tax would be applied to distributed profits defined as dividends,
share buybacks and deemed corporate distributions related to items, including
the payment of non-business expenses and tax haven payments. There would be
no dierentiation in tax rates by sector or size of profit to minimize complexity;
Distributions would be taxed without being limited by undistributed profit
accounts in the year
21
;
Intercorporate dividends would be tax free between resident companies,
as under the existing corporate income tax, to avoid double taxation. Once
the tax is applied to corporate distributions of one company paid to another
company, it would be exempt from further tax on distributed profits thereafter;
Profit distributions from aliates in treaty countries with at least 10 per cent
ownership would pass through to investors as exempt income. Otherwise,
foreign tax payments would serve as a credit to be claimed against the tax
on distributed profits. If a minimum tax is imposed on foreign aliates as
currently discussed internationally, it would apply to countries with a tax rate
of at least 15 per cent on accrued income;
Canadian residents would receive a dividend tax credit based on the corporate
tax rate applied to deemed distributions from the corporations;
Since reinvested earnings that increase the value of the company’s shares
are not taxed, a concessionary tax on capital gains on the sale of shares by
investors is no longer necessary. Thus, capital gains would be taxed at a rate of
100 per cent rather than subject to partial exclusion (inflation adjustments are
recommended to avoid taxing nominal capital gains) . Real estate capital gains
could be fully taxed (with inflation adjustment);
Withholding taxes on dividends paid to non-residents would continue to be
applied according to treaty arrangements;
While Estonia exempts all reinvested profits, whether sourced from income or
capital gains, the proposal is adjusted to include a refundable withholding tax
on investment income and capital gains earned by companies so that investors
21
This is the approach used in Estonia. It is possible to limit the tax on distributions to income earned in the
year and undistributed profits in past years. Distributions in excess of undistributed profits would be treated
as a return of capital.
16
have less incentive to use the corporate form to avoid personal income taxes.
This tax on passive income and capital gains reduces the deferral advantage
of leaving passive income undistributed to shareholders, following a similar
approach used for Canadian-controlled private corporations.
We estimate the revenue-neutral corporate tax on distributed profits would be 16 per
cent at the federal level (Table 3). The revenue-neutral corporate tax rate is estimated
using 2018 corporate dividend payment in Statistics Canada data. Share buybacks
are added as a proportion of dividends based on the Federal Reserve study for OECD
countries for 2012-2014 (15 per cent of dividends) (Federal Reserve 2017). Values are
brought forward to 2022/3 based on the Economic and Fiscal Update 2020 estimates
of corporate income taxes. The provincial average tax rate on corporate distributed
profits is estimated to be 11.2 per cent. That results in the same corporate tax revenues
collected as in 2022 ($37 billion). Dividend distributions could decline in favour of
retained earnings, but with the increase in the capital gains tax rate, it is not clear what
the ultimate impact would be on revenues.
One might be surprised that the revenue-neutral corporate tax on distributed profits
that exempts reinvested profits altogether is so close to the existing corporate income
tax rate (26.2 per cent). Corporate taxable income ($370 billion in the fiscal year
2022/3) is substantially below corporate operating profits ($515 billion) due to tax
incentives. Since reinvested profits are exempt, tax incentives, including non-refundable
investment and employment tax credits, no longer generate tax savings for companies.
In Table 3, any additional personal capital gains tax on realizations by moving to full
taxation of capital gains from disposing corporate shares is not included as revenue.
Some revenue loss would be experienced, resulting from a lower personal tax rate on
ineligible dividends, resulting from a higher corporate tax rate on distributed profits.
Any additional revenues could be used to reduce personal income tax rates.
Table 3. Revenue Estimate from Corporate Tax in Distributed Profits for 2022
Tax Base (billions) Federal Corporate Taxes (billions)
Projected 2022/3 Corporate Tax Base and Revenues* $370 $52.7
Corporate Operating Profits Before Tax $515
Dividends** $287
Deemed Distributions*** $43
Corporate Tax on Distributed Profits Base $330
Corporate Tax on Distributed Profits at 16 Per Cent $52.8
*Based on the Fall Economic Update, Finance Canada, 2020, https://budget.gc.ca/fes-eea/2020/home-
accueil-en.html.
**November Statistics Canada (n.d.) Table 36-10-0117-01. Includes dividends paid to residents and non-
residents.
***Includes share buybacks.
Using this revenue-neutral corporate tax rate of 27 per cent on distributed profits, the
METR on capital can be estimated (Table 4). The purpose of shifting from the existing
corporate income tax to a tax on distributed profits is to reduce the eective tax
17
rate on capital funded by reinvested profits to zero.
22
However, the tax on corporate
distributions would increase the cost of raising equity finance depending on the
dividend payout ratio (this argument is based on the traditional theory of finance
(Mintz 1995)). Other taxes, such as sales taxes on capital purchases and real estate
transfer taxes, continue to be applied.
Comparing Table 4 with Table 1 (where temporary accelerated depreciation is assumed
to have been fully phased out), we see that the average METR falls from 19.5 per cent
to 15.8 per cent. Several sectors would be more heavily taxed since tax incentives no
longer matter to the investment decision — these sectors benefited from low marginal
eective tax rates. Thus, the METR for manufacturing rises from 13.7 per cent to
14.2 per cent, primarily due to the loss of tax preferences in Quebec and the Atlantic
Provinces. The METRs remain highest in British Columbia, Saskatchewan and Manitoba
due to retail sales taxes that add to capital purchase costs.
Table 4: Corporate Tax on Distributed Profits at a 27 Per Cent Rate
EVALUATION
The corporate tax on distributed profits has several advantages in reducing distortions,
and some disadvantages.
Intertemporal Distortions
The intertemporal distortion would be reduced, indicating a greater demand for
investment, even under the traditional theory used here to model equity financing. If
investment is solely equity financed by retained earnings, the METRs in Table 4 would
be closer to zero, leaving retail sales tax on capital purchases in B.C., Saskatchewan
and Manitoba and property transfer taxes on capital investment (as well as annual
municipal property taxes that are not included in these calculations).
22
When retained earnings is the marginal source of equity finance, the dividend tax has no impact on
investment decisions. Distribution taxes are simply lump sum taxes with the opportunity of retained earnings
finance being the after-tax profit used to finance investment with the future discounted after-tax dividend
payments being return on investment. This has been referred to as the new view of equity finance, implying
that the distribution tax rate is irrelevant to the investment decision (Auerbach and Hassett 2003).
18
Inter-industry and Inter-asset Distortions
The variation in METRs across industries would be significantly reduced relative to
the current system. The range in METRs across industries is fairly tight: 14.2 per cent
in manufacturing to 17.6 per cent in services. In our analysis, we assume the same
financing ratios in order to focus on tax dierences. If dividend payouts vary across
industries (40 per cent for all firms), the METR variation would be greater than what
has been estimated. The overall dispersion index, discussed above, declines from
7.2 per cent to 0.3 per cent, substantially reducing inter-asset and inter-industry tax
distortions (the remaining distortions are related to sales taxes on capital purchases
and land transfer taxes). Obviously, the corporate income tax would be substantially
simplified, reflecting the reduction in policy-induced distortions.
International Distortions
The tax on corporate distributed profits would put domestic and foreign companies on
a level playing field from the perspective of Canadian corporate taxation. It would also
treat domestic and foreign investments made by Canadian resident companies equally.
It would reduce the incentive to borrow debt from abroad since interest deductions
would not aect the amount of corporate tax on distributed profits.
Risk-taking Distortions
Given that corporate tax would only be paid when profits are distributed, losses are not
relevant in determining the tax on distributions. The corporate tax, therefore, would
impose no additional tax on risky investments. A corporation with temporary losses
would pay its tax on distributed profits, but this would fall on investors as the dividends
distributed to investors would be reduced.
Financing Distortions
Compared to the existing corporate income tax, the tax on distributed profits
(including share buybacks) could create more neutrality among financing sources.
However, the impact of taxation on financial decision-making is complicated to
evaluate given the plethora of domestic and international personal and corporate tax
rates. As shown in Table 5 below for Canadian residents:
Integration of corporate and personal income taxes is preserved for dividends,
employment income and other chargeable deductions (rents, royalties and
fees). The dividend tax credit would be based on the current treatment of
eligible dividends (at the federal rate of 16 per cent and provincial rate of 11
per cent). The combined corporate tax on distributed profits and personal
tax on dividends would be equal to the tax on employment income and other
deductible payments from the corporate tax base;
As capital gains realizations from the sale of shares are fully taxed at the
personal level, the tax on capital gains realizations would be the same as that
on dividends, assuming shares are held for only one year. However, if shares
are held for longer periods, the personal income tax is deferred until the shares
19
are sold — this would lower the eective tax rate on capital gains, favouring
retained earnings as a source of finance;
Given interest deductibility is of no value at the corporate level, companies
will have an incentive to reduce leverage compared to the existing system.
However, debt finance could be favoured relative to equity to avoid the
corporate tax on profit distributions if companies borrow from tax-exempt
pension funds or low-tax investors at home or abroad. If debt is borrowed
from tax haven entities or tax-exempt shareholders, the loan interest could be
deemed to be distribution of profits.
Under the existing corporate tax system, Canadian corporate and withholding taxes
are credited against foreign taxes. However, in the case of dividends paid by aliates
operating in Canada, these are generally tax exempt abroad by capital exporting
countries. Since only profit distributions are taxed by Canada under its corporate tax,
foreign companies will be discouraged to remit income to their parent, resulting in
some loss in Canadian tax revenues.
23
Given that Canada does not tax capital gains
earned by foreign investors (except for qualifying real estate and resource properties),
Canada might want to consider deeming capital gains upon disposal of assets by non-
residents as a dividend distribution.
Table 5. Tax on Income with an Ontario Corporate Tax on Distributed Profits
Dividend Paid to
Canadian Investor
Reinvested Earnings Employment, Interest or Royalty Income
Corporate Profits $100 $100 $100
Corporate Tax $27 0 $0
Net Profit $73 $100 $100
Personal Tax (1) $23 $50 $50
Net Income $50 $50 $50
(1) Assumes the investor is the high-income investor at a rate of 50 per cent. Dividend tax rate includes
the dividend tax credit equal to 27 per cent of pre-corporate tax distributed profits. Capital gains are fully
taxed.
Overall, the proposal would encourage foreign investors to reinvest profits in Canada.
Given that non-residents pay capital gains taxes to their home countries and not
Canada, foreign investors could have an advantage over Canadian investors in buying
Canadian assets if Canada moves to full capital gains taxation (the U.S. tax rate on long-
term capital gains is 20 per cent, close to the current Canadian capital gains tax rate).
Business Organization Distortions
The current corporate income tax favours the corporate form since the profit rate is
below the top personal income tax rate. With a corporate tax on distributed profits,
the tax on retained earnings would be deferred until the profit is distributed, thereby
providing an additional incentive to incorporation.
23
Roughly $50 billion in corporate dividends are distributed to non-residents.
20
In contrast, business income is attributed to owners of sole proprietorships, branches,
trusts and partnerships that are subject to current personal or corporate taxation. With
the ability to defer the profit tax, the corporate form of business organization would
have an advantage over other business organizational forms. Nonetheless, the incentive
to avoid current tax by leaving income within the corporation is lessened by taxing
passive income from reinvested profits.
OVERALL ASSESSMENT
A corporate tax on distributed profits provides several advantages in reducing
distortions. Being more neutral, it would be an improvement over the current corporate
income tax. However, it is not a perfect solution. Some investors will be able to defer
paying personal taxes by leaving profits in the company rather than distributing them.
On the other hand, to the extent that the existing corporate tax is shifted back on labour
or forward to consumers, the tax on corporate distributions might be less regressive
by primarily aecting the amount of profits distributed to investors. The corporate
tax would be substantially simplified by eliminating distinctions between eligible and
ineligible dividends since only one corporate tax rate would be applied to distributed
profits. As well, many rules associated with tax incentives would no longer be needed
since reinvested profits would be exempt from taxation.
24
Other anti-avoidance rules
may be required but, overall, the corporate tax system should be less complex.
Tax reform is never simple and raises a host of transition issues. Distributions paid from
past taxed profits would be taxed unless exempted initially. Pools of unused tax losses
carried forward from earlier years would no longer have value, resulting in a one-time
wealth tax.
This dierent approach to corporate tax reform could be implemented on an
experimental basis. For example, given Quebec and Alberta collect their own corporate
income taxes, they could try this approach first. However, the international issues would
be complex for provincial administration — a corporate tax on distributed profits might
need to apply regardless of whether the global distributions have already been taxed.
An allocation formula to determine distributed profits for a province would be needed.
To avoid negotiations over a new formula, the existing apportionment rules using
payroll and sales revenues could be used.
24
Investment tax credits could be provided by making them refundable against the corporate distribution tax.
21
CORPORATE TAX ON DISTRIBUTED RENTS
Economic rents are returns on an investment in excess of the normal net-of-risk return
on the investment. Another way of describing economic rent is the surplus income in
excess of the economic costs of production, including risk costs. In theory, economic
rents can be taxed heavily — even up to a 100 per cent tax rate — without reducing
the incentive to make the investment and produce from it. However, extremely high-
rent tax rates could encourage highly profitable projects to shift to jurisdictions with
lower tax rates. Given that risk costs are not observable, economic rents are less than
observable profits.
25
Much, though by no means all, of the activity that produces economic rents is carried
out by business corporations in the private sector. Such rents may be earned from
ownership of intellectual property and economic or regulatory barriers to entry
preventing competition, in addition to ownership of assets, such as natural resources
and land. This leads to the idea that, at the very least, corporations deriving earnings
in the form of economic rents should be taxed directly on those rents in order to
prevent the possibility of reducing the rent tax if it were only taxed at the shareholder
level. As some of these rents are shifted to other parts of the economy through higher
labour payments, for example, or internationally through licensing agreements, rents
need not show up as profit but instead be reflected as employment compensation,
royalties or fees.
The concept of a corporate tax applying to rents became popular among economists
in the late 1970s with the publication of the 1978 U.S. Treasury report headed by David
Bradford (1986) and the U.K. Meade Report (Institute of Fiscal Studies 1978). A key
point is that the imputed costs of debt and equity finance would be deductible from
the corporate base, unlike the measurement of shareholder profits, which only provides
for a deduction for the cost of debt finance.
Two methods have been suggested to tax economic rents:
cash flow and (economic) profit
bases.
26
The cash flow base would be revenue net of current and capital expenditure.
Given the expensing of capital expenditure, which is equivalent to the present value of
depreciation and financing costs, neither depreciation nor financing expenses would
be deductible from the tax base. The alternative approach is the economic profits base,
which is defined as revenues net of the economic cost of depreciation, debt interest
expense and an allowance for the corporate equity expense (ACE).
Although the cash flow tax approach has been used for mining and oil/gas rent
taxation (Chen and Mintz 2012), it has not been generally used for corporate taxation.
One reason is that the tax is not easily applicable to rent unless cash flow includes not
only real transaction flows, but also financial ones (Institute of Fiscal Studies 1978),
which can be quite complicated once dealing with financial innovations. Another is
that it works best with a personal tax applied to expenditure (earnings net of savings
25
A rent tax may not raise much revenue once risk costs are deducted.
26
Bradford (1986) proposed a cash flow approach. The Mirrlees Report (2011) recommended the economic
profits approach as an alternative rent tax.
22
or exempting the normal return to capital), as discussed in the Meade Report (1978),
Bradford (1986) and the Mirrlees Report (2011).
The economic profit approach has been more easily adaptable for the economy as a
whole. It has been implemented by providing an allowance for equity financing (ACE)
with equity including both retained earnings and shareholder-contributed capital. The
ACE is typically set at the government long-term bond rate (such as 10 years), which
in recent years could be negative.
27
The ACE was initially adopted in Croatia, but later
disbanded. It was then used in Belgium to replace its low-tax regime for headquarters
that was being challenged by the European system. Given the accelerating cost of the
ACE deduction, Belgium later limited the ACE to new equity issues, similar to Italy.
Today the ACE is used by several countries, such as Belgium, Brazil, Cyprus, Italy, Malta
and Turkey.
The cash flow and economic profit approaches are not the only ones. Another would
be to tax shareholder distributions net of equity issues (King 1987). Thus, the above
proposal could be adjusted by treating new equity issues as a negative distribution that
would be deducted from the tax base. If the tax base is negative, the amount could be
carried back or carried forward at an interest rate reflecting any risk should losses not
be eventually used. This would result in the neutral treatment of investment decisions
under the corporate tax. If the personal tax is also reformed by allowing savings to be
deducted (dissavings would be fully taxed and interest would not be deductible), it
would then parallel the corporate income tax, removing both corporate and personal
tax on the normal return to investment (rents would be taxed fully).
28
If only the corporate tax is changed into a rent tax, several consequences would be
involved.
First, treating new equity issues as a negative distribution would narrow the corporate
tax base, resulting in a higher corporate tax rate if corporate tax revenues are kept
constant. Using Statistics Canada data, the estimated revenue-neutral federal-
provincial corporate income tax rate would be 55 per cent if new equity issues were
subtracted from the distributed profits base.
29
A high corporate tax on dividend
payments would encourage companies to pass out rent in other forms of payment to
27
Belgium set the ACE to be equal to -0.16 per cent in 2021 for large companies and 0.34 per cent for small and
medium-size companies: https://www.oecd.org/tax/tax-policy/tax-database/corporate-and-capital-income-
tax-explanatory-annex.pdf.
28
Boadway and Tremblay (2014) recommend the corporate cash flow tax in Canada with dividends and
realized capital gains taxed at a rate of 100 per cent under the personal income tax (see also McKenzie
and Smart 2019). The corporate-only cash flow tax provides substantial benefits by not aecting the
investment decision, leaving aside the global personal tax eects on capital decisions. It also raises a number
of complexities that are not simple to address: consistency with the personal income tax, measuring the
appropriate exempt return on capital, taking into account risk, treatment of tax losses and international tax
planning considerations. See the Technical Committee on Business Taxation (1997) and Mintz (2018). See also
the discussion below regarding the mixing of a personal income tax with a rent tax on corporate distributions.
29
Calculations based on 2019 data from Statistics Canada.
https://www150.statcan.gc.ca/t1/tbl1/en/tv.action?pid=3610011601.
https://www150.statcan.gc.ca/t1/tbl1/en/tv.action?pid=3610057801&pickMembers%5B0%5D=2.6&cubeTimeFrame.
startMonth=01&cubeTimeFrame.startYear=2020&cubeTimeFrame.endMonth=01&cubeTimeFrame.
endYear=2021&referencePeriods=20200101%2C20210101.
23
resident and non-resident shareholders.
Second, the deductibility of new equity from the corporate tax base suggests that
it would be possible to eliminate the dividend tax credit and capital gains exclusion
preference since the corporate tax sole purpose is to withhold rents, not income
accruing to investors. However, with the deduction for new equity issues at the
corporate level, the corporate tax would be paid on that portion of profit reflecting
rents. Rents distributed to resident investors as dividends and capital gains, however,
would be double taxed. For example, if there is no dividend tax credit, the eective rate
on rents paid as dividends to an Ontario investor in Table 3 would be close to 67 per
cent. Non-resident investors may also be subject to double taxation on rents paid out
as dividends and realized capital gains. Companies will, therefore, look to avoid higher
tax rates on rents distributed as equity income by resorting to non-profit payments
that are deductible at the corporate level — employment compensation, leasing,
royalties, management fees, etc. It would also open new opportunities for domestic
and international tax planning that would need to be considered.
Nonetheless, as part of a major tax reform of both corporate and personal income
taxes towards rent-based taxation, the option of shifting to a rent-based corporate tax
on distributions is intriguing. It would need further study going beyond this paper.
CONCLUSIONS
Canada has taken many steps to reform its corporate income tax since 1985 by
reducing corporate rates and broadening the corporate tax base. However, Canada’s
corporate income tax remains distortionary, with high economic, compliance and
administrative costs. Even without politically motivated tax incentives, the lack of
indexation for inflation, imperfect loss refundability, international tax interactions and
other complexities make a perfect corporate income tax unachievable.
In recent years, the corporate tax reforms have been reversed with the introduction
of new tax incentives after 2015. Yet, these changes have failed to lead to a better
investment performance in Canada. If Canada is to build up its productive capacity in
the post-COVID world, a big-bang approach to corporate tax could be more successful.
Here, I propose converting the corporate income tax into a tax on distributed profits.
A business tax reform along these lines would put Canada into a unique position to
attract investment, as well as reduce many distortions in the business tax system. It is
not perfect, but it is better than what we currently have. It could also be turned into a
rent tax by treating new equity issues as negative dividends but this approach would
need fundamental reform of both the corporate and personal income taxes.
24
REFERENCES
Auerbach, A. J., and K. A. Hassett. 2003. “On the Marginal Source of Investment
Funds.” Journal of Public Economics, vol. 87, issue 1, January: 205232.
Baker, Scott, Stephen Teng Sun, and Constantine Yannelis. 2020. “Corporate Taxes and
Retail Prices.” NBER Working Paper no. 27058. April. http://www.nber.org/papers/
w27058.
Baqaee, David, and Emmanuel Farhi. 2020. “Productivity and Misallocation in General
Equilibrium.” Quarterly Journal of Economics. Oxford University Press, vol. 135(1):
pages 105163.
Bartholdy, J., G. Fisher, and J. Mintz. 1987. “Taxation and Financial Policy of Firms:
Theory and Empirical Application to Canada.” Economic Council of Canada.
Bazel, P., and J. Mintz. 2019. “Is Accelerated Depreciation Good or Misguided Policy.”
Canadian Tax Journal, vol. 67, issue 1: 41–55.
———. 2020. “The 2019 Tax Competitiveness Report: Canada’s Investment and Growth
Challenge.” SPP Research Papers. The School of Public Policy, University of
Calgary. March.
———. 2021. “2020 Tax Competitiveness Report: Canada’s Investment Challenge.
SPP Research Paper, 14(21). The School of Public Policy, University of Calgary.
September.
Boadway, R., and J-F. Tremblay. 2014. “Corporate Tax Reform: Issues and Prospects for
Canada.” Mowat Research #88. Mowat Centre, University of Toronto.
Bradford, D. 1986. Untangling the Income Tax. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University
Press.
Da-Rocha, Jose-Maria, Diego Restuccia, and Marina M. Tavares. 2021. “Policy
Distortions and Aggregate Productivity with Endogenous Establishment-Level
Productivity.” Working Papers tecipa-702. University of Toronto, Department of
Economics.
Dahlby, Bev, and Ergete Ferede. 2018. “The Marginal Cost of Public Funds and the
Laer Curve: Evidence from the Canadian Provinces.”FinanzArchiv: Public Finance
Analysis, vol. 74 issue 2: 173–199.
Chen, D., and J. Mintz. 2012. “Capturing Economic Rents from Resources Through
Royalties and Taxation.” SPP Research Papers, 5(30). The School of Public Policy,
University of Calgary. October.
Federal Reserve. 2017. “Corporate Buybacks and Capital Investment: An International
Perspective, Accessible Data.” April 11. https://www.federalreserve.gov/econres/
notes/ifdp-notes/corporate-buybacks-and-capital-investment-an-international-
perspective-accessible-20170411.htm#fig3.
Goolsbee, A. 1998. “Investment Incentives, Prices and the Supply of Capital Goods.”
Quarterly Journal of Economics, 113(1): 121–148.
25
Government of Canada. 1966. “Report of the Royal Commission on Taxation.” Carter
Report. Ottawa: Privy Council Oce.
———. 1997. “Report of the Technical Committee on Business Taxation.” Report. Dept.
of Finance.
———. 2017. “Tax Planning Using Private Corporations.” Technical briefing. Dept. of
Finance. https://www.canada.ca/content/dam/fin/migration/n17/data/tppc-pfsp-
eng.pdf.
Institute of Fiscal Studies. 1978. “The Meade Report: The Structure and Reform of
Direct Taxation.” Report by a committee chaired by Professor J. E. Meade. London:
The Institute for Fiscal Studies.
Jog, V., and J. Mintz. 1989. “Corporate Tax Reform and its Economic Impact: An
Evaluation of the June 18, 1987 Proposals.” In The Economic Impacts of Tax Reform,
J. Mintz and J.Whalley, eds. Toronto: Canadian Tax Foundation.
Keightley, M., and M. Sherlock. 2014. “The Corporate Income Tax: Overview and Options
for Reform.” Congressional Research Oce. https://fas.org/sgp/crs/misc/R42726.
pdf.
King, M. 1987. “The Cash Flow Corporate Income Tax.” In The Eects of Taxation on
Capital Accumulation, M. Feldstein, ed. National Bureau of Economic Research,
Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Maso, J., J. Meriküll, and P. Vahter. 2011. “Gross Profit Taxation Versus Distributed
Profit Taxation and Firm Performance: Eects of Estonia’s Corporate Income Tax
Reform.” Working Paper 81-2011. University of Tartu, Faculty of Economics and
Business Administration.
McKenzie, K., and E. Ferede. 2018. “Who Pays the Corporate Tax?: Insights from the
Literature and Evidence for Canadian Provinces.” In Reforming the Corporate Tax in
a Changing World, B. Dahlby, ed. Toronto: Canadian Tax Foundation and School of
Public Policy, University of Calgary.
McKenzie, K., and M. Smart. 2019. “Tax Policy Next to the Elephant: Business Tax
Reform in Wake of the US Tax Cuts and Jobs Act.” Commentary 537. C.D. Howe
Institute.
Miller, M. H. 1977. “Debt and Taxes.” Journal of Finance,vol. 32: 261–275.
Mintz, J. 1988. “An Empirical Estimate of Refundability and Eective Corporate Tax
Rates.” Quarterly Journal of Economics. February: 225–31.
———. 1995. “The Corporation Tax: A Survey.” Fiscal Studies, vol. 16, issue 4: 23-
68. Reprinted in The Economics of Tax Policy, M. Devereux, ed. Oxford: Oxford
University Press: 127-188.
———. 2018. “Directions for Corporate Income Tax Reform in Canada.” In Reforming
the Corporate Tax in a Changing World, B. Dahlby, ed. Toronto: Canadian Tax
Foundation: 219–59.
26
Mintz, J., and S. Richardson. 2006. “Income Trusts and Integration of Business and
Investor Taxes: A Policy Analysis and Proposal.” Canadian Tax Journal, vol. 54, issue
2: 359403.
Mintz J., Patrick Smith, and V. Balaji Venkatchalam. 2021. “A New Approach to
Improving Small-Business Tax Competitiveness.” SPP Research Paper, Volume
14(24). The School of Public Policy, University of Calgary. October.
Mintz, J., and Alfons Weichenrieder. 2010. The Indirect Side of Direct Investment.
Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Mirrlees, James, Stuart Adam, Tim Besley, Richard Blundell, Stephen Bond, Robert
Chote et al. 2011. Tax by Design. Institute for Fiscal Studies. The Mirrlees Review.
Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.
OECD. 2021. “Tax Challenges Arising from the Digitalisation of the Economy – Global
Anti-Base Erosion Model Rules (Pillar Two): Inclusive Framework on BEPS.
https://www.oecd.org/tax/beps/tax-challenges-arising-from-the-digitalisation-of-
the-economy-global-anti-base-erosion-model-rules-pillar-two.pdf.
Statistics Canada. n.d. Table 36-10-0117-01.
———. 2021. “Revenue, Expenditure and Budgetary Balance – General Governments
(x1,000,000).” Accessed July 21, 2021. https://www150.statcan.gc.ca/t1/tbl1/en/
tv.action?pid=3610047701.
27
About the Author
Dr. Jack M. Mintz
28
ABOUT THE SCHOOL OF PUBLIC POLICY
The School of Public Policy has become the flagship school of its kind in Canada by providing a practical, global and
focused perspective on public policy analysis and practice in areas of energy and environmental policy, international policy
and economic and social policy that is unique in Canada.
The mission of The School of Public Policy is to strengthen Canada’s public service, institutions and economic performance
for the betterment of our families, communities and country. We do this by:
Building capacity in Government through the formal training of public servants in degree and non-degree programs,
giving the people charged with making public policy work for Canada the hands-on expertise to represent our vital
interests both here and abroad;
Improving Public Policy Discourse outside Government through executive and strategic assessment programs, building
a stronger understanding of what makes public policy work for those outside of the public sector and helps everyday
Canadians make informed decisions on the politics that will shape their futures;
Providing a Global Perspective on Public Policy Research through international collaborations, education, and community
outreach programs, bringing global best practices to bear on Canadian public policy, resulting in decisions that benefit
all people for the long term, not a few people for the short term.
The School of Public Policy relies on industry experts and practitioners, as well as academics, to conduct research in their
areas of expertise. Using experts and practitioners is what makes our research especially relevant and applicable. Authors
may produce research in an area which they have a personal or professional stake. That is why The School subjects all
Research Papers to a double anonymous peer review. Then, once reviewers comments have been reflected, the work is
reviewed again by one of our Scientific Directors to ensure the accuracy and validity of analysis and data.
The School of Public Policy
University of Calgary, Downtown Campus
906 8th Avenue S.W., 5th Floor
Calgary, Alberta T2P 1H9
Phone: 403 210 3802
DISTRIBUTION
Our publications are available online at www.policyschool.ca.
DISCLAIMER
The opinions expressed in these publications are the authors' alone and
therefore do not necessarily reflect the opinions of the supporters, sta,
or boards of The School of Public Policy.
COPYRIGHT
Copyright
©
Mintz 2022. This is an open-access paper distributed under
the terms of the Creative Commons license CC BY-NC 4.0, which allows
non-commercial sharing and redistribution so long as the original author
and publisher are credited.
ISSN
ISSN 2560-8312 The School of Public Policy Publications (Print)
ISSN 2560-8320 The School of Public Policy Publications (Online)
DATE OF ISSUE
February 2022
MEDIA INQUIRIES AND INFORMATION
For media inquiries, please contact Morten Paulsen at 403-220-2540.
Our web site, www.policyschool.ca, contains more information about
The School's events, publications, and sta.
29
RECENT PUBLICATIONS BY THE SCHOOL OF PUBLIC POLICY
CANADIAN ARCTIC MARINE TRANSPORTATION ISSUES, OPPORTUNITIES AND CHALLENGES
https://www.policyschool.ca/wp-content/uploads/2022/02/NC28_Marine-Transportation_Lasserre.pdf
Frédéric Lasserre | February 2022
EXISTING AND PENDING INFRASTRUCTURE PROJECTS: POTENTIAL COMPATIBILITY WITH THE CANADIAN NORTHERN CORRIDOR
https://www.policyschool.ca/wp-content/uploads/2022/01/NC27_Infrastructure-Projects_Munzur-2.pdf
Alaz Munzur | January 2022
SOCIAL POLICY TRENDS: TYPES OF HOMELESSNESS
https://www.policyschool.ca/wp-content/uploads/2022/01/January-SPT-Kneebone.pdf
Ronald Kneebone | January 2022
ENERGY AND ENVIRONMENTAL POLICY TRENDS: WHAT’S DRIVING THE COST OF DRIVING?
https://www.policyschool.ca/wp-content/uploads/2022/01/EFL33_EEPT_Jan2022.pdf
G. Kent Fellows and Gregory Galay | January 2022
FROM NATIONAL ACCORDS TO BILATERAL AGREEMENTS: TRANSFORMING CANADIAN HEALTH CARE INTERGOVERNMENTALISM
https://www.policyschool.ca/wp-content/uploads/2022/01/HC1_Cdn-Health-Care_McIntosh-DeCorby.pdf
Tom McIntosh and Alanna DeCorby | January 2022
THE CHA AND BEYOND: THE ROLE OF LEGISLATION IN NATIONAL REFORM IN HEALTH CARE
https://www.policyschool.ca/wp-content/uploads/2022/01/HC3_CHA-and-Beyond_Forest-Stoltz.pdf
Pierre-Gerlier Forest and Lori Stoltz | January 2022
INNOVATION IN THE U.S. HEALTH CARE SYSTEMS ORGANIZATION AND DELIVERY
https://www.policyschool.ca/wp-content/uploads/2022/01/HC8_US-Health-Care_DiStefano-et-al.pdf
Michael DiStefano, So-Yeon Kang, Mariana Socal and Gerard Anderson | January 2022
ADVANCING SUPPLY-CHAIN RESILIENCE FOR CANADIAN HEALTH SYSTEMS
https://www.policyschool.ca/wp-content/uploads/2022/01/HC6_Supply-Chain-Resilience_Snowdon.pdf
Anne Snowdon | January 2022
INTERNATIONAL POLICY TRENDS: TRAVEL BANS AND OMICRON
https://www.policyschool.ca/wp-content/uploads/2022/01/IPT-Travel-Ban-FINAL-USE.pdf
Robert Falconer | January 2022
SOCIAL POLICY TRENDS: THE HOLIDAYS AND SOCIAL POLICY ISSUES
https://www.policyschool.ca/wp-content/uploads/2021/12/SPT-dec.pdf
Ronald Kneebone, Margarita Wilkins, Ali Jadidzadeh and Robert Falconer | December 2021
A PATH TO IMPROVED HEALTH WORKFORCE PLANNING, POLICY & MANAGEMENT IN CANADA: THE CRITICAL COORDINATING AND CONVENING
ROLES FOR THE FEDERAL GOVERNMENT TO PLAY IN ADDRESSING EIGHT PER CENT OF ITS GDP
https://www.policyschool.ca/wp-content/uploads/2021/12/HC5_Improved-Health-Care_Bourgeault.pdf
Ivy Bourgeault | December 2021
FIVE POLICY RECOMMENDATIONS FOR THE CANADIAN FEDERAL GOVERNMENT TO ACCELERATE THE GROWTH AND IMPACT OF DIGITAL HEALTH
https://www.policyschool.ca/wp-content/uploads/2021/12/HC7_Digital-Health_Kelley-et-al.pdf
Leah Kelley, Denise Zarn, Vanessa Kishimoto and Trevor Jamieson | December 2021
HEALTHCARE FUNDING POLICIES FOR REDUCING FRAGMENTATION AND IMPROVING HEALTH OUTCOMES
https://www.policyschool.ca/wp-content/uploads/2021/12/HC4_Health-Outcomes_Sutherland.pdf
Jason Sutherland | December 2021