%
%
%
Personal banking
services market study:
Review of the Commerce
Commission’s draft report
Report prepared for BNZ
18 April 2024
0
DRAFT & LEGALLY PRIVILEGED
Prepared for the purposes
of legal advice
Contents
Glossary 2
Scope and introduction 4
The extent of competition for personal banking products 5
Profitability 40
Appendix VAR estimation procedure 45
Public Version | Glossary
1
Table of Tables
Table 1: Report structure and content ..................................................................................................................... 4
Table 2: Factors needed for Commission’s preliminary findings to hold true and our assessment of evidence . 8
Table 3: Deloitte Access Economics’ results of price responsiveness for advertised mortgage rates ................ 15
Table 4: Deloitte Access Economics’ results of price responsiveness for $10,000 minimum advertised term
deposit rates............................................................................................................................................................. 16
Table 5: Deloitte Access Economics’ results of price responsiveness for $50,000 minimum advertised term
deposit rates............................................................................................................................................................. 17
Table 6: VAR equations ............................................................................................................................................ 48
Table 7: Underlying VAR specification for advertised mortgage rates ................................................................. 49
Table 8: Underlying VAR specification for advertised $10,000 minimum term deposit rates ............................ 50
Table 9: Underlying VAR specification for advertised $50,000 minimum term deposit rates ............................ 50
Table of Figures
Figure 1: Rank of advertised rates for 1-year mortgages, 4 January 2010 to 30 November 2023 (1 indicates
‘best’ rate) ................................................................................................................................................................ 11
Figure 2: Rank of advertised rates for 1-year term deposits, 4 January 2010 to 30 November 2023 (1 indicates
‘best’ rate) ................................................................................................................................................................ 12
Figure 3: Estimated regional volume share of registered mortgages from 1 January 2023 to 6 December 2023
.................................................................................................................................................................................. 21
Figure 4: Proportional change in value share Asset quality Housing Loans series (percentage change, June
2018 to December 2023) ........................................................................................................................................ 26
Figure 5: Proportional change in value of deposits on balance sheet (percentage change, June 2018 to
December 2023) ...................................................................................................................................................... 26
Figure 6: Estimated regional volume share of registered mortgages of Kiwibank and its next closest rival from
1 January 2023 to 6 December 2023 ...................................................................................................................... 28
Figure 7: 6-month term deposit, floating mortgage and short-term wholesale rates (2000 2024) ................ 30
Figure 8: Annual home lending growth as a multiple of system growth for ANZ, ASB, Westpac, BNZ and
Kiwibank ................................................................................................................................................................... 32
Figure 9: Premium on 6-month term deposit compared to on-call savings and term deposits share of total
deposits .................................................................................................................................................................... 33
Figure 10: Spread between advertised 1-year mortgage rates and 1-year term deposit rates .......................... 33
Figure 11: Changes in provider of home loans as a percentage of total new home lending for all purposes ... 35
Figure 12: [ ] ............................................................................................................................................................ 36
Figure 13: [ ] ............................................................................................................................................................ 36
Figure 14: [ ] ............................................................................................................................................................ 36
Figure 15: [ ] ............................................................................................................................................................ 37
Figure 16: [ ] ............................................................................................................................................................ 38
Figure 17: Cost to income ratio for selected comparison countries ..................................................................... 41
Figure 18: Cost-to-income ratio for New Zealand banks ....................................................................................... 42
Public Version | Glossary
2
Glossary
Acronym
Full name
ACT
Australian Competition Tribunal
ANZ
ANZ Bank New Zealand Limited
ASB
ASB Bank Limited
BNZ
Bank of New Zealand
BOB
Bank of Baroda (New Zealand) Limited
BOI
Bank of India (New Zealand) Limited
CCB
China Construction Bank (New Zealand) Limited
Commission
Commerce Commission
Co-op
The Co-operative Bank Limited
CTI
Cost-to-Income
D-SIB
Domestic Systemically Important Bank
FLP
Funding for Lending Programme
FMA
Financial Markets Authority
GFC
Global Financial Crisis
HHI
Herfindahl-Hirschman Index
H-Statistic
Panzar-Rosse-H-Statistic
ICBC
Industrial and Commercial Bank of China (New Zealand) Limited
IRF
Impulse Response Function
LINZ
Land Information New Zealand
LSAP
Large Scale Asset Purchase
LVR
Loan-to-value
MBIE
Ministry of Business, Innovation and Employment
NBDT
Non-Bank Deposit Taker
NIM
Net Interest Margin
OCR
Official Cash Rate
PIP
Preliminary Issues Paper
RBNZ
Reserve Bank of New Zealand
RBS
Royal Bank of Scotland
Public Version | Glossary
3
[ ]
[ ]
SBS
Southland Building Society
SFA
Stochastic Frontier Analysis
TLF
Term Lending Facility
TSB
TSB Bank Limited
VAR
Vector Autoregressive Regression
Westpac
Westpac New Zealand Limited
Public Version | Scope and introduction
4
Scope and introduction
Purpose
1. Deloitte Access Economics (we, us or our) have been engaged by Bank of New Zealand (BNZ) to
review the Commerce Commission’s (the Commission) Draft Report into personal banking
services market study, released 21 March 2024. This report provides our review of the
Commission’s preliminary findings that:
1.1. The major banks; ANZ Bank New Zealand Limited (ANZ), ASB Bank Limited (ASB),
Westpac New Zealand (Westpac) and BNZ, do not currently face strong competition and
can be characterised as a stable oligopoly.
1.2. There are high levels of observed profitability.
Structure and scope of this report
2. The structure of this report is outlined in Table 1 below:
Table 1: Report structure and content
Content
Analysis on no clear price leadership, pricing relationships across banks and
products, regional differences and discretionary discounting.
The degree to which personal banking products are homogenous.
The extent of competition from Kiwibank.
The extent to which the New Zealand banking sector has been subject to supply-
and demand-side shocks.
The extent of switching and multihoming, regulatory conditions of entry and
expansion and economies of scale and scope.
The levels of accounting and economic efficiency in the New Zealand banking sector
and implications for observed levels of profitability.
Regulatory conditions of entry and expansion explain observed profitability trends.
Source: Deloitte Access Economics
Authors of the report
Liza Van Der Merwe (Partner), Nigel Annett (Partner), Dr Ric Simes (Principal, Australia), Mayuresh Prasad
(Associate Director), Elri Pienaar (Manager), Ayden Dickins (Analyst) and Emily Barron (Analyst)
Public Version | The extent of competition for personal banking products
5
The extent of competition for
personal banking products
Key points:
Outcomes in dynamic and differentiated markets with several, but not an infinite, number of firms can range
from intensely competitive to significantly uncompetitive.
The Commission’s preliminary view is that personal banking services can be characterised as a stable two-
tiered ‘oligopoly’, with Kiwibank ‘stuck’ in the middle, and a risk of tacit coordination. This suggests an
outcome that is not workably competitive.
For the Commission’s preliminary view to hold true, we consider a range of factors need to be present. Our
review of the evidence suggests that many of the factors do not hold:
o While pricing is fundamentally driven by capital markets, there is no apparent price leader for headline
rates across mortgages and term deposits. Our empirical analysis also suggests the presence of dynamic
and varying relationships between advertised rates across multiple products. Analysis of LINZ data
suggests regional differences in competition, with smaller banks and other institutions such as TSB, SBS
and Nelson Building Society providing an increased competitive constraint in certain regions.
o The Commission also finds no price leader across effective rates for new owner-occupier home lending
and a weak correlation between headline and effective rates. We acknowledge this latter fact is likely to
add to search and switching costs, dampening demand side pressures.
.
o We agree that the presence of price matching can act to soften competition in markets. However, in the
context of the variability in rates, relationships and regional competitive conditions, price matching is
likely to be aimed at ensuring banks are competitively pricing and sending signals that they are low-
priced (i.e., competition at work).
o We acknowledge personal banking products are homogenous, but only consider this to be true to a
degree, with non-price factors a key dimension of competition. Discretionary discounts also add an
element of differentiation, and the multiplicity of products within personal banking services add further
differentiation and reflect that consumers have different preferences across products.
o The view that Kiwibank is ‘stuck’ in the middle gives disproportionate weight to its current market
position. A wider analysis of the available evidence (i.e., its above system growth, consumer perceptions
found in the Verian survey and LINZ data-based volume shares) suggest it is a closer constraint to ANZ,
ASB, Westpac and BNZ than found by the Commission. Reflecting this, and found by the Commission’s
econometric paper, market concentration is moderate and has decreased notably between 2016 and
2022.
o The banking sector has been subject to significant disruption from macroeconomic events, such as the
GFC and COVID-19. We consider that the periods of less intense competition, identified by the
Commission, coincide with periods of heightened uncertainty and policy interventions by the RBNZ.
o We agree with the Commission that impediments to switching are generally perceived, rather than
actual. Mortgages are found to be a conduit to switching across other personal banking services and of
late, switching has increased. There is further evidence of increased ‘multihoming’, use of brokers and
increased digitalisation.
Public Version | The extent of competition for personal banking products
6
o We agree that regulatory conditions impact entry and expansion, and these interact with economies of
scale and scope. However, such regulations exist for a reason, and the trade-off between competition
and financial stability needs to be considered carefully.
Overall, our review of the evidence suggests competition in personal banking services is more dynamic and
effective than the stable oligopoly found by the Commission in its Draft Report.
o We consider there is differentiated and varying price competition across multiple products, with added
variability from regional differences in competition. We consider Kiwibank is a closer competitive
constraint to ANZ, ASB, Westpac and BNZ, adding asymmetry to the market. Switching for gateway
products such as mortgages have increased of late and may continue to increase through brokers and
increased ‘multihoming’ and digitalisation.
o The consequence of the above is that, in our view, the market is unlikely to be conducive to a situation
where banks can reach mutually acceptable outcomes that are workably uncompetitive. We consider, as
recently found by the Australian Competition Tribunal, that while personal banking services may be
vulnerable to coordination, the conditions for coordination have reduced. Evidence suggests:
Market concentration is moderate and has decreased notably between 2016 and 2022. Although
there are symmetries across banks, there are also asymmetries across major banks, such as
across volume shares in different regions across banks and volume shares changing over time.
There is also no evidence to suggest coordination on non-price aspects and pass-through of
changes in regulatory costs.
Prevalence of discretionary pricing is high, accounting for 50% to 60% of home loans, which
detracts from price transparency; along with the increasing impact of brokers, which reduces
search and switching costs.
The role of capital markets is important, but so too are external macroeconomic factors, leading
to times of uncertainty and volatility.
Kiwibank provides a stronger competitive constraint relative to the maverick benchmark of
Macquarie referred to by the Commission. For example, Kiwibank now has at least 50% of the
lowest market share of a “major bank” when compared to Macquarie, which has a share of a
third of the lowest market share of a “major bank”. The Commission, nonetheless, considers
Macquarie to be a disrupter.
Framework for our review
3. We consider that competition between banks for personal banking services is best characterised
by differentiated competition. That is, while price is a key dimension across which banks
compete, they differentiate their lending and deposit offerings along a number of lines.
Differentiating factors include non-price factors such as the range of products, service,
perceptions of trust and security, innovation, product design, customer support, digital
capabilities and brand awareness.
1
The nature of competition for personal banking services is
also dynamic.
4. Markets with several, but not an infinite number of firms, that interact over time can be found in
all countries across a broad range of sectors.
2
In such dynamic markets, with several, but not an
infinite number of firms, a wide range of potential competitive outcomes are possible. The
outcome is also difficult to predict. “Folk theorem” of markets with several, but not an infinite
number of firms, suggest that “anything can happen”, ranging from intensely competitive to
1
Commerce Commission “Personal banking services market study Draft report” (21 March 2024) at [2.55].
2
See, for example, OECD “Oligopoly markets”, available at https://www.oecd.org/daf/competition/oligopoly-
markets.htm#:~:text=Oligopoly%20markets%20are%20markets%20dominated,at%20least%20appear%20that%20way.
Public Version | The extent of competition for personal banking products
7
monopoly outcomes if competitors are sufficiently patient. Being “sufficiently patient” means
valuing future higher prices and profits over current sales at lower prices.
3
5. Put simply, outcomes in dynamic markets with several firms, but not an infinite number of firms,
can range from intensely competitive to some that are significantly less so.
6. The Commissions preliminary view on the state of competition for personal banking services
suggests an outcome that is closer to an uncompetitive outcome. For this to be true, we
consider the following factors would need to be present:
4
6.1. An ability for firms to reach mutually acceptable outcomes or focal points and the
ability to detect and punish deviations from such outcomes
5
, which may, in turn, depend
on factors such as:
6.1.1. The presence of largely homogenous products.
6
6.1.2. A small number of firms that are of similar size and cost structure.
7
6.1.3. An absence of ‘outside’ or ‘maverick’ firms within the market.
8
6.1.4. Stable market conditions with low innovation and uncertainty.
9
6.2. An inability for consumers to easily switch between rival firms.
10
6.3. Impediments to entry and expansion.
11
7. These factors are similar to factors the Commission considers “are consistent with the
conditions for coordination
12
and that the Australian Competition Tribunal (ACT) considered in
its recent decision relating to the proposed merger of ANZ and Suncorp.
13
Summary of our review
8. Table 2 below lists the above factors, the Commission’s view and our assessment of the
evidence against them.
3
Applications by Australia and New Zealand Banking Group Limited and Suncorp Group Limited [2024] ACompT 1 at [381]. See also Europe
Economics “Study on Assessment Criteria for Distinguishing between Competitive and Dominant Oligopolies in Merger Control Final Report
for the European Commission Enterprise Directorate General” (2001) at 15.
4
We would emphasise this is not a complete list of factors that would need to be present for the likelihood of uncompetitive outcomes.
5
As many potential outcomes are possible in oligopoly settings, firms need to be able coordinate on one of the many possible outcomes.
Focal points, and the ability to detect and punish deviations from such points, may enable firms to reach mutually acceptable outcomes in a
market that are above competitive levels see Applications by Australia and New Zealand Banking Group Limited and Suncorp Group Limited
[2024] ACompT 1 at [382].
6
If products are differentiated and firms produce a large number of products, it can be argued that firms will have difficulties in determining
a complete schedule of mutually acceptable outcomes see Europe Economics “Study on Assessment Criteria for Distinguishing between
Competitive and Dominant Oligopolies in Merger Control Final Report for the European Commission Enterprise Directorate General” (2001)
at 32.
7
Asymmetries between firms in terms of factors such as cost structures have been found to make tacit coordination more difficult see, for
example, R Rothschild “Cartel stability when costs are heterogeneous” (1999) 17(5) International Journal of Industrial Organisation 717.
8
Smaller or ‘fringe’ firms can play an important role in the ability of firms to reach outcomes that are uncompetitive or collusive. See, for
example, R Selten “A Simple Model of Imperfect Competition Where Four are Few and Six Are Many” (1973) 2 International Journal of Game
Theory 141.
9
Unpredictable periods of downturns or high demand may make it difficult for firms to reach mutually acceptable outcomes. Periods of
downturns may be interpreted as ‘cheating’ and growing demand may increase the inventive for firms to deviate from a mutually acceptable
outcome and gain market share see, for example, Julio J Rotemberg and Garth Saloner “A Supergame-Theoretic Model of Price Wars during
Booms” (1986) 76(3) The American Economic Review 390.
10
In a competitive market, customers usually have ready access to the information they need to make well informed purchasing decisions,
and the ability to easily switch between rival suppliers see Commerce Commission “Market Study Guidelines” (2020) at [17].
11
At its extreme, markets characterised by perfect contestability would keep prices in a market at competitive levels, even only with a few
firms in the market see, John C Panzar, Robert D Willig and William Baumol Contestable Markets and the Theory of Contestable Markets
(Harcourt Brace Jovanovich, New York, 1982).
12
Commerce Commission “Personal banking services market study – Draft report” (21 March 2024) at [2.67]. See also Commerce
Commission “Mergers and acquisitions guidelines” (May 2022) at [3.89].
13
Australian Competition Tribunal “Applications by Australia and New Zealand Banking Group Limited and Suncorp Group Limited [2024]
ACompT 1” (February 2024) at [F.2.].
Public Version | The extent of competition for personal banking products
8
Table 2: Factors needed for Commission’s preliminary findings to hold true and our assessment of evidence
Factors
Commission’s findings
Our assessment of evidence
Price
transparency / An
ability for firms to
reach mutually
acceptable
outcomes and
detect and
punish deviations
A risk of accommodating behaviour (or tacit
coordination), as the major banks have broadly similar
cost structures, can readily observe and respond to each
other’s pricing and regularly interact across a range of
services.
14
Established patterns of price matching reduce incentive to
compete hard on interest rates.
15
No clear price leaders for advertised or effective rates, varying
pricing relationships across banks and products, discretionary
discounts and regional variability in competition all add to
difficulty in achieving mutually acceptable outcomes.
While we acknowledge that price matching may soften
competition, we consider the context in which it takes place is
crucial. Given no clear price leadership, varied pricing
relationships and regional differences in competition, price
matching is likely to be a signal that a bank is low-priced and is
pricing competitively.
Homogenous
products
Services are largely homogenous.
16
There is a degree of non-price competition on metrics like
brand reputation and service. The strong brands of the
major banks reinforce the current market structure,
whereas customer service levels do not appear to
materially impact shares of supply.
17
Discretionary discounting is common, being applied to
between 50% and 60% of lending by volume.
18
Banking products are only homogenous to a degree, with non-
price factors such as service quality differentiating products.
There is a multiplicity of products in personal banking services
(each with distinct consumer preferences and a different set
of competitors and strategies).
While prices are advertised and most firms share common
cost benchmarks (e.g., the Official Cash Rate, 90-day bank bill
yields), discretionary discounts do make it harder to observe
competitor prices (Although we acknowledge this latter fact is
likely to soften demand side competition).
A small number
of firms / High
concentration
and lack of
‘maverick’ or
outside firms
The major banks, ANZ, ASB, BNZ and Westpac, do not
currently face strong competition when providing
personal banking services.
19
Providers of personal banking services can be split into
two-tiers. The first tier comprises the four major banks.
The second tier comprises the smaller registered banks
and non-banks. Kiwibank is ‘stuck in the middle’ of these
two-tiers.
20
Kiwibank was found to have an impact on the pricing of ANZ,
ASB, Westpac and BNZ.
The econometrics paper commissioned by the Commission
found only moderate levels of concentration in the market
and found that it has decreased between 2016 to 2022.
Smaller banks provide constraint on a regional basis, adopt
different business models and may focus on particular market
segments, lowering conditions to entry as a result.
Symmetries
across producers
It is implied by the Commission’s finding that major banks
have broadly similar cost structures and do not face
strong competition when providing personal banking
services.
There are asymmetries in market shares between ANZ, ASB,
Westpac and BNZ.
Kiwibank is a competitive constraint, adding significant
asymmetry. The likes of TSB, SBS and Nelson Building Society
also drive regional differences in competition.
Little innovation,
stable demand
and lack of supply
shocks/volatility
Competition between the major banks is sporadic. Each of
the major banks has greater or lesser growth ambitions at
any point in time, but none are consistently offering ‘best
in market’ home lending interest rates.
21
There is limited investment and low prioritisation into
core banking systems by the major banks and Kiwibank.
22
There have not been disruptive innovations observed
overseas from fintechs and progress towards open
banking has been slow.
23
Banking products are subject to supply-side and demand-side
shocks, especially during periods of global uncertainty such as
the GFC or COVID-19 pandemic.
In Deloitte Access Economics’ Preliminary Issues Paper (PIP)
response, we note that innovation is a broad concept and
impacts of ongoing improvements to both processes and
existing products need to be considered as part of the
assessment in this study.
24
An inability for
consumers to
easily switch
between rival
firms
Impediments to searching and switching reduces
competitive pressure on the major banks.
25
Consumers of personal banking services tend to be
“sticky”, with consumers often defaulting to their existing
provider when adding or renewing services.
26
There is a significant degree of customer inertia in
personal banking, however some impediments to
switching are perceived.
27
Multibanking’ (or multihoming) is increasing.
28
Impediments to switching are generally perceived rather than
actual, and there is evidence of increased switching across
mortgages, which are a ‘gateway’ for switching across other
products.
Evidence of increased ‘multihoming’ over time.
Brokers and increased digitalisation are likely to further
increase switching.
Impediments to
entry and
expansion
The banking sector is highly regulated, and regulation is
the “single most important factor constraining providers’
ability to enter”.
29
We agree there are regulatory conditions to entry and
expansion, which interact with economies of scale, and are
exacerbated by lack of scale in New Zealand.
Source: Deloitte Access Economics
Public Version | The extent of competition for personal banking products
9
9. In short, evidence points to competition for personal banking services being more competitive
and dynamic than the stable oligopoly found by the Commission in its Draft Report:
9.1. There is a degree of differentiation across personal banking products, driven by non-
price factors and discretionary discounts. Evidence suggests that most banks respond to
other banks advertised rates, irrespective of their size and structure. Combined with
varying price leadership, dynamic price relationships, and regional differences in
competition, this suggests that the ability for banks to achieve mutually acceptable
outcomes or to coordinate is difficult.
9.2. The constraint that Kiwibank provides on ANZ, ASB, Westpac and BNZ is greater than that
implied by current market shares alone. Our review of the evidence suggests that
Kiwibank acts as a constraint on ANZ, ASB, Westpac and BNZ pricing, has been growing at
levels above ‘system’ growth (implying it is winning market share) and is considered a
closer alternative to ANZ, ASB, Westpac and BNZ by consumers (based on the
Commission’s own survey).
9.3. Impediments to switching are generally perceived, rather than actual, and switching for
mortgages, a gateway for wider product switching, has increased of late. There is
evidence of increased ‘multihoming’ over time alongside brokers and increased
digitalisation is likely to facilitate further switching.
10. We have noted some inconsistencies in the Commission’s Draft Report, which form the basis for
its conclusion of a stable oligopoly. We encourage the Commission in its Final Report to resolve
these inconsistencies, and consider the impact of them on its findings on the nature of
competition for personal banking services. These inconsistencies include, for example:
10.1. The Commission found that Kiwibank is outside of the top-tier stable oligopoly but also
acts to influence the pricing of ANZ, ASB, Westpac and BNZ.
10.2. The Commission found that there is stable sporadic competition, with price matching
and possibility of price coordination but contrasted with the presence of different
strategies pursued by different banks at different times, with no clear price leader and a
weak correlation between advertised and effective rates.
10.3. The Commission said that it could not rule out accommodating behaviour for home loans
but a lower risk for deposits. This is despite pricing across both home loans and deposits
being considered together by banks’ pricing committees, as emphasised by the
Commission.
30
14
Commerce Commission “Personal banking services market study – Draft report” (21 March 2024) at 31.
15
Ibid, at 73.
16
Ibid, at [2.39.6].
17
Ibid, at 31.
18
Ibid, at [4.26].
19
Ibid, at 31.
20
Ibid, at 31.
21
Ibid, at 73.
22
Ibid, at 223.
23
Ibid, at 223.
24
Deloitte Access Economics “Personal banking services: Consumer switching, conditions of entry and expansion, profitability and
innovation” (7 September 2023), at [67 73].
25
Commerce Commission “Personal banking services market study – Draft report” (21 March 2024), at 195.
26
Ibid, at 31.
27
Ibid, at 195.
28
Ibid, at 34.
29
Ibid, at 159.
30
Ibid, at [4.28].
Public Version | The extent of competition for personal banking products
10
Headline pricing is variable across both mortgage and term deposit products
11. Fundamentally, pricing of mortgage and term deposit products is largely driven by capital
markets. Conceptually, this could provide a “focal point” around which tacit coordination could
take place (e.g., “leader-follower” behaviour where one firm determines how the market will
respond to these changes). However, as discussed in detail below, neither our analysis nor the
Commission’s finds any evidence of tacit coordination of this form.
12. As the Commission notes, each of the major banks (which includes Kiwibank) have at different
times taken best in market position on key home lending products, reflecting their individual
strategies at these times. None of these five providers have consistently offered lowest headline
rates over time over a 5-year period to 22 September 2023.
31
13. We have extended the Commission’s ranking analysis on the advertised rates of ANZ, ASB,
Westpac, BNZ and Kiwibank, using advertised mortgage and term deposit rates from
interest.co.nz data from 4 January 2010 to 30 November 2023. Our analysis focusses on 1-year
mortgage products and 1-year $10,000 minimum term deposit products, as these represent a
large proportion of products by value.
32
31
Ibid, [4.54], [Figure 4.6] and [4.58].
32
For term deposits, see RBNZ “Banks: Liabilities – Deposits by size (value) (S45)” (March 2024) and for mortgages RBNZ “Banks: Assets –
Loans fully secured by residential mortgage, by time until next repricing (S33) (March 204). We note that the RBNZ only published data
surrounding time to next repricing (as opposed to product duration). However, as the share of mortgages with approximately a year until
repricing has been relatively stable, this suggests that 1-year home loan products are relatively common.
Public Version | The extent of competition for personal banking products
11
Figure 1: Rank of advertised rates for 1-year mortgages, 4 January 2010 to 30 November 2023 (1 indicates ‘best’
rate)
Source: Deloitte Access Economics analysis of interest.co.nz data
Public Version | The extent of competition for personal banking products
12
Figure 2: Rank of advertised rates for 1-year term deposits, 4 January 2010 to 30 November 2023 (1 indicates
‘best’ rate)
Source: Deloitte Access Economics analysis of interest.co.nz data
Public Version | The extent of competition for personal banking products
13
14. As can be seen from Figure 1 and Figure 2 above, and consistent with the Commission’s
preliminary findings, there is no discernible price-leader or pricing pattern among ANZ, ASB,
Westpac, BNZ and Kiwibank across mortgage and term deposit products, at least from weekly
advertised pricing data.
33
15. The Commission also noted that it similarly observed no evidence of a price leader when
considering agreed interest rates on mortgages.
34
16. As the Commission notes, “leader-follower” behaviour can be consistent with (some methods
of) tacit coordination:
35
This occurs where one firm in the market (the leader) raises prices on the understanding that other firms (the
followers) will match this movement. This mutual understanding allows firms to exploit collective market
power and drive prices up, creating clear competition concerns.
17. Our analysis of headline rates, as well as the Commission’s own analysis, finds no evidence of
“leader-follower” behaviour in the market. Instead, analysis of headline advertised rates
suggests they are highly variable, meaning that firms are unlikely to be able to reach mutually
acceptable outcomes or focal points when setting prices.
18. Rather, we consider the evidence points to price competition being present in the market, with
factors such as external influences and balance sheet management also impacting how a bank
prices its products at any given time.
Our empirical analysis also does not find any discernible pricing patterns for
headline rates
Overview of our approach
19. In addition to the price ranking analysis above, we undertook empirical analysis under a model
that captures the potential for dynamic and inter-linking relationships between banks’
advertised rates for mortgages and term deposits. While the Appendix provides further details
of the data and methodology, this section of the report provides an overview of the key aspects
of our empirical approach.
20. To assess the responsiveness of banks’ personal home loan and term deposit advertised rates to
each other, we employed a vector autoregressive regression (VAR). Under the VAR system of
equations, it was assumed that a bank’s advertised rates for a particular week depend on:
20.1. A relevant cost benchmark rate as at that week (e.g., for variable rate mortgages, the 90-
day bank bill rate).
36
20.2. Previous weeks’ advertised rates of that bank’s rates.
20.3. Previous weeks’ advertised rates of competing banks’ rates.
21. Our analysis was based on weekly interest.co.nz data for advertised rates from 4 January 2002
to 3 November 2023.
21.1. For the mortgage rates, our analysis was conducted for the advertised variable rate, 1-
year fixed, 2-year fixed, 3-year fixed, 4-year fixed and 5-year fixed rate for personal home
lending products.
33
Given that for many home lending providers, including ANZ, ASB, Westpac, BNZ and Kiwibank, decisions on pricing are made by pricing
committees who meet regularly (for example, weekly) - Commerce Commission “Personal banking services market study – Draft report” (21
March 2024) at [4.28] and [4.29] we consider weekly data is likely to be sufficiently high in frequency to capture discernible pricing patters
for personal home lending products.
34
Ibid, at [4.59.1].
35
Ibid, at [Footnote 284].
36
We have included these cost benchmarks to control for the variation in advertised rates that are caused by movements in capital markets.
Public Version | The extent of competition for personal banking products
14
21.2. For the term deposit rates, our analysis was conducted for advertised 6-month, 1-year,
2-year, 3-year, 4-year, and 5-year rates for personal term deposit products and
separately for term deposits of $10,000 and $50,000 minimums respectively.
22. The banks considered under the VAR system of equations estimated were ANZ, ASB, Westpac,
BNZ, Kiwibank, and other registered banks (other banks). The other banks’ advertised rates were
calculated as a simple average of advertised rates for personal home lending and term deposit
products from registered banks who are not ANZ, ASB, Westpac, BNZ, and Kiwibank.
37
23. Having estimated the VAR system of equations, we were able to test and verify:
23.1. Whether the relevant cost benchmark is statistically significant in explaining the
advertised mortgage and term deposit rates of banks.
23.2. The set of banks that statistically significantly explained the rates of the other banks.
38
23.3. The patterns of the statistically significant relationships found across different mortgage
and term deposit products.
Limitations
24. We would note that our results focus only on the presence of a statistically significant causal
relationship (i.e., do the advertised rates of bank X impact those of bank Y), not how
economically significant that relationship is (i.e., it cannot tell us by how much the advertised
rates of bank X impact those of bank Y).
25. While this is an important consideration in interpreting our results, the analysis can still provide useful
insights into the nature of competition in mortgages and term deposits, as it can provide a view on:
25.1. The number of firms across which statistically significant relationships are found.
25.2. How similar banks are in terms of size and structure across which statistically significant
relationships are found.
25.3. The patterns of the statistically significant relationships found.
26. Our results suggest a degree of dynamism for mortgages and term deposits. The results from
our empirical analysis of mortgage and term deposit products are provided below. Table 3 to
Table 5 illustrate the statistically significant relationships found between the relevant cost
benchmark and advertised rates for banks (i.e., if the rates of one bank statistically significantly
impact the rates of another bank across mortgage and term deposit products). For example,
when considering if other banks explain advertised rates in Table 3 below, we find that other
banks advertised 5-year mortgage rates statistically significantly impact BNZ and Kiwibank’s 5-
year mortgage rates at the 99% confidence level, ASB’s 5-year mortgage rates at the 95%
confidence level and ANZ’s 5-year mortgage rates at the 90% confidence level.
37
For example, other banks included in the VAR model for advertised floating mortgage rates were Bank of China, HSBC, HSBC Premier,
Heartland, ICBC, Kookmin, National Bank, SBS, TSB and Westpac Trust. For the VAR model for advertised $10k minimum 6-month term
deposit rates, the other banks variable consisted of Bank Direct, Bank of Baroda, Bank of India, Co-operative Bank, HSBC, ICBC, Kookmin,
National Bank and TSB. As the interest.co.nz dataset we used extends back to 2002, several older sub-brands, such as Westpac Trust, are
present in our dataset. To account for the possibility that such sub-brands followed and executed different competitive strategies, we
included these within other banks variable.
38
We used Granger-causality to establish whether the rates of one bank are statistically significant in explaining those of another. This is
discussed in further detail in the Appendix.
Public Version | The extent of competition for personal banking products
15
Table 3: Deloitte Access Economics’ results of price responsiveness for advertised mortgage rates
Product
Variable
1-year
2-year
3-year
4-year
5-year
Does the cost
benchmark explain
advertised rates?
90-day bank bill
90-day bank bill
2-year swap rate
3-year swap rate
4-year swap rate
5-year swap rate
Do ANZ rates explain
advertised rates?
ASB
BNZ
Kiwibank
Other banks
BNZ
Kiwibank
Other banks
Kiwibank
Other banks
Westpac
Other banks
Do ASB rates explain
advertised rates?
ANZ
BNZ
ANZ
ANZ
ANZ
ANZ
BNZ
Other banks
BNZ
BNZ
Kiwibank
Kiwibank
Kiwibank
Kiwibank
Kiwibank
Other banks
Other banks
Westpac
Westpac
Other banks
Do Westpac rates
explain advertised
rates?
ANZ
ANZ
ANZ
BNZ
ANZ
ANZ
ASB
BNZ
ASB
Kiwibank
BNZ
ASB
BNZ
BNZ
Other banks
Kiwibank
Kiwibank
Other banks
Other banks
Other banks
Do BNZ rates explain
advertised rates?
ANZ
ANZ
ANZ
Westpac
Westpac
Westpac
ASB
ASB
Kiwibank
Kiwibank
Westpac
Other banks
Other banks
Kiwibank
Other banks
Do Kiwibank rates
explain advertised
rates?
ANZ
ASB
ANZ
BNZ
ANZ
ANZ
ASB
Westpac
BNZ
Westpac
BNZ
ASB
BNZ
Other banks
Other banks
Other banks
Westpac
BNZ
Other banks
Other banks
Westpac
Other banks
Do other banks rates
explain advertised
rates?
ANZ
ASB
ANZ
ANZ
ANZ
ANZ
BNZ
BNZ
BNZ
ASB
ASB
ASB
Westpac
Kiwibank
BNZ
Westpac
BNZ
Westpac
Kiwibank
Source: Deloitte Access Economics
Public Version | The extent of competition for personal banking products
16
Table 4: Deloitte Access Economics’ results of price responsiveness for $10,000 minimum advertised term
deposit rates
Product
6-month
1-year
2-year
3-year
4-year
5-year
Does the cost
benchmark explain
advertised rates?
90-day bank bill
90-day bank bill
2-year swap rate
3-year swap rate
4-year swap rate
5-year swap rate
Do ANZ rates explain
advertised rates?
ASB
ASB
ASB
ASB
ASB
ASB
Kiwibank
BNZ
BNZ
BNZ
BNZ
BNZ
Westpac
Kiwibank
Kiwibank
Kiwibank
Kiwibank
Kiwibank
Other banks
Westpac
Other banks
Other banks
Do ASB rates explain
advertised rates?
ANZ
BNZ
ANZ
ANZ
BNZ
BNZ
BNZ
Kiwibank
Kiwibank
BNZ
Kiwibank
Other banks
Kiwibank
Other banks
Westpac
Kiwibank
Westpac
Westpac
Other banks
Westpac
Other banks
Other banks
Other banks
Do Westpac rates
explain advertised
rates?
ANZ
ANZ
BNZ
ASB
ASB
ANZ
ASB
ASB
Kiwibank
Kiwibank
BNZ
BNZ
Other banks
Other banks
Kiwibank
Kiwibank
Other banks
Do BNZ rates explain
advertised rates?
ANZ
ANZ
ANZ
ANZ
ANZ
ANZ
ASB
ASB
ASB
ASB
Kiwibank
Kiwibank
Kiwibank
Kiwibank
Kiwibank
Kiwibank
Westpac
Westpac
Other banks
Westpac
Westpac
Other banks
Other banks
Other banks
Other banks
Do Kiwibank rates
explain advertised
rates?
ANZ
ANZ
ANZ
ANZ
ANZ
ANZ
ASB
ASB
ASB
ASB
ASB
ASB
BNZ
BNZ
BNZ
BNZ
BNZ
Other banks
Other banks
Westpac
Westpac
Westpac
Westpac
Other banks
Other banks
Other banks
Other banks
Do other banks rates
explain advertised
rates?
ANZ
ANZ
ASB
ASB
BNZ
BNZ
Kiwibank
Kiwibank
Westpac
Source: Deloitte Access Economics
Public Version | The extent of competition for personal banking products
17
Table 5: Deloitte Access Economics’ results of price responsiveness for $50,000 minimum advertised term
deposit rates
Product
6-month
1-year
2-year
3-year
4-year
5-year
Does the cost
benchmark explain
advertised rates?
90-day bank bill
90-day bank bill
2-year swap rate
3-year swap rate
4-year swap rate
5-year swap rate
Do ANZ rates explain
advertised rates?
ASB
ASB
ASB
ASB
ASB
ASB
Westpac
BNZ
BNZ
BNZ
BNZ
BNZ
Other banks
Kiwibank
Westpac
Kiwibank
Kiwibank
Westpac
Kiwibank
Other banks
Do ASB rates explain
advertised rates?
ANZ
BNZ
ANZ
ANZ
BNZ
BNZ
BNZ
Kiwibank
Kiwibank
BNZ
Kiwibank
Other banks
Kiwibank
Other banks
Westpac
Kiwibank
Westpac
Other banks
Other banks
Westpac
Other banks
Other banks
Do Westpac rates
explain advertised
rates?
ANZ
ASB
BNZ
Other banks
Kiwibank
ANZ
ASB
BNZ
Other banks
Other banks
Kiwibank
BNZ
Kiwibank
Other banks
Kiwibank
Other banks
Other banks
Do BNZ rates explain
advertised rates?
ANZ
ANZ
ANZ
ANZ
ANZ
ANZ
Kiwibank
ASB
ASB
Kiwibank
Kiwibank
Kiwibank
Other banks
Kiwibank
Kiwibank
Westpac
Westpac
Westpac
Other banks
Do Kiwibank rates
explain advertised
rates?
ANZ
ANZ
ANZ
ANZ
ANZ
ASB
ASB
ASB
ASB
ASB
ASB
Other banks
BNZ
BNZ
BNZ
BNZ
BNZ
Other banks
Westpac
Westpac
Westpac
Other banks
Other banks
Other banks
Do other banks rates
explain advertised
rates?
ANZ
ANZ
ANZ
ANZ
ASB
ASB
Kiwibank
BNZ
BNZ
Kiwibank
Kiwibank
Westpac
Westpac
Source: Deloitte Access Economics
Public Version | The extent of competition for personal banking products
18
27. As can be seen from Table 3 to Table 5 above, we find that:
27.1. Changes in the relevant cost benchmark for the personal home lending and term deposit
products (e.g., the 90-day bank bill rate for 1-year fixed mortgages) are highly statistically
significant in explaining:
27.1.1. Almost all banks’ advertised rates across all the personal home lending products
we analysed.
39
27.1.2. All banks’ advertised rates across all personal term deposit products we analysed.
27.2. Specifically, we found that out of 90 equations modelled (6 different banks, across 3
product types and 5 product durations), the relevant cost benchmark was statistically
significant in 88 of them.
27.3. For the statistically significant relationships we observe between the relevant cost
benchmark and advertised rates for banks, we find the expected positive relationship
(that is, an increase in the relevant cost benchmark leads to an increase in the bank’s
advertised rates) for
27.3.1. All banks for all home lending products
27.3.2. All banks for all term deposit products.
27.4. In other words, we find, as expected, that capital markets have a key role in explaining
the variation in advertised mortgage and term deposit rates.
40
27.5. Almost all banks we studied statistically significantly impact at least one other bank
across all mortgage and term deposit products
41
, meaning banks of differing size and
ownership structure impact mortgage and term deposit rates. This evidence suggests
that most banks respond to other banks advertised rates, irrespective of their size or
structure.
27.6. From our analysis we find a degree of dynamism, and variety in the pattern of
relationships found, with no particular bank or groups of banks determining advertised
rates across both mortgages and $10,000 and $50,000 minimum term deposit products.
For example, for advertised mortgage rates, the results indicate that ANZ and Westpac's
rates have an impact over the variable rates of every other bank, but that BNZ has an
impact on the rates of every bank for the 1-year rates, Kiwibank’s rates have an impact
on the rates of every bank for the 5-year rates and other bank rates impact ANZ, ASB,
BNZ and Westpac’s advertised 3-year and 5-year rates.
27.7. In addition, there are a number of ‘indirect’ causal relationships. For example, our results
for term deposits suggest that the advertised rates of ANZ for the 2-year $10,000
minimum product have an impact on the advertised rates of Kiwibank, who in turn
impact the advertised rates of every other banks 2-year term deposit advertised rates.
Similarly, ANZ’s advertised rates for the 6-month $10,000 minimum product have an
impact on the advertised rates of other banks, who in turn, impact the advertised rates
of ANZ, ASB, BNZ, Kiwibank and Westpac.
39
We found that for 28 out of 30 total equations for home lending products, the cost benchmark was statistically significant, except for BNZ’s
one-year and two-year rates, for which the wholesale rate was found to not be statistically significant at any conventional significance level.
40
We consider this accords with economic theory. Even in hypothetical monopoly settings, the rate of pass-through of an industry-wide
change in cost for a monopolistic firm facing a linear demand curve and a constant marginal cost would be expected to be passed through at
a rate of 50% - see RBB Economics for the Office of Fair Trading “Cost pass-through: theory, measurement and potential policy implications”
(February 2014) at [Chapter 3.3.].
41
The only exception was ANZ for 2-year and 4-year mortgage products and other banks, who are not found to influence other banks
statistically significantly for 2-year to 5-year minimum $10,000 deposit products and the 3-year and 5-year minimum $50,000 term deposit
products.
Public Version | The extent of competition for personal banking products
19
27.8. Our results are broadly consistent with the Commission’s preliminary findings on its
review of a broader evidence base, in that Kiwibank has an impact on ANZ, ASB, Westpac
and BNZ across mortgages and term deposits.
42
27.9. However, we consider that the Commission has understated the likely constraint
Kiwibank provides on ANZ, ASB, Westpac and BNZ. We discuss this in more detail in the
sections below.
28. In summary, our results suggest competition across advertised mortgage and term deposit rates
can be characterised by the interaction between several banks with differing characteristics, and
the presence of dynamic or varying relationships amongst them. Similar to our analysis of
headline interest rates in the prior section of the report, we consider the presence of dynamic or
varying relationships are likely to make reaching mutually acceptable outcomes when setting
prices difficult.
There are important regional dynamics at play
29. While it is useful to consider the extent of competition for personal banking services on a
national basis, and indeed many banks adopt a national strategy,
43
there are important regional
dynamics at play which can be overlooked.
Our analysis of Land Information New Zealand data
30. We have analysed mortgage registration data from Land Information New Zealand (LINZ) to
understand regional dynamics at play. This analysis of LINZ data enables us to get a view on the
proportion of new and refixed mortgages across banks between 1 January 2023 and 6
December 2023.
44
The analysis provides an estimate of volume shares for mortgages across
banks.
30.1. Our analysis uses the title memorials dataset from LINZ. When a mortgage on a property
title is registered or varied, it creates an entry in the title instruments table. This table
also records information about the location of the property and entities with an interest
in the instrument (in the case of a mortgage, the institution issuing the mortgage).
45
30.2. We were then able to build a dataset of mortgages registered (or varied) in 2023 (up to 6
December 2023). For each mortgage, we were able to determine the region that the
property is in and the name of the institution issuing it. We were then able to use this to
calculate estimates of the volume share (of new or varied registrations of mortgages) by
bank by land district.
46
30.3. We have also mapped the land districts recorded by LINZ onto local government
regions.
47
This required combining Northland and Auckland, Waikato and Bay of Plenty,
Nelson and Tasman, and Wellington and Manawatu.
42
Commerce Commission “Personal banking services market study – Draft report” (21 March 2024) at [4.53].
43
We note ANZ, ASB, BNZ, Kiwibank and Westpac all commented in their PIP submissions that they adopt a national view of the market. See,
for example, BNZ “Bank of New Zealand’s submission on the Commerce Commission’s preliminary issues paper regarding the market study
into personal banking services” (7 September 2023) at [6.4] [6.6] and Kiwibank “Kiwibank’s response to the Commerce Commission’s
Preliminary Issues Paper” (7 September 2023) at 9.
44
The LINZ the dataset covered data up to 06 December 2023 as at when we accessed it.
45
The encumbrancee table, via the encumbrance share and encumbrance tables, links a title instrument to the entity with an interest in it (an
encumbrance being an interest in the title such as a lease or mortgage, and encumbrancee being the entity holding that interest). See LINZ
“LINZ Data Service: Full Landonline Dataset – Data dictionary and data models” (Version 3.0, July 2023) at [4.19], [4.20], [4.21] & [4.79].
46
We did this by considering title instruments where the instrument type was recorded as “M”, and for each of these looked up the
associated encumbrancee. We could then cut the dataset by land district and calculate volume shares by entity. We note that not all
encumbrancees were financial institutions, but the vast majority were. We also tested including “VM” types, however found no entries in
2023. Based on correspondence with LINZ, we understand that often variations can be entered in the dataset as a newly registered
mortgage.
47
The LINZ land districts and our mapping are North Auckland (Northland and Auckland), South Auckland (Waikato and Bay of Plenty),
Hawkes Bay (Hawkes Bay), Gisborne (Gisborne), Taranaki (Taranaki), Wellington (Wellington and Manawatu, as well as the Chatham Islands),
Nelson (Nelson and Tasman), Marlborough (Marlborough), Westland (West Coast), Canterbury (Canterbury), Otago (Otago) and Southland
(Southland), see LINZ “NZ Land Districts” (March 2024) available at https://data.linz.govt.nz/layer/50785-nz-land-districts/
Public Version | The extent of competition for personal banking products
20
31. We also undertook cleaning to ensure consistency across entity names (e.g., control for changes
in legal names and inconsistent capitalisation), fix spelling mistakes and identify erroneous
entries. For example, in 2023, ANZ was entered correctly 29,391 times and we identified 4
erroneous entries with incorrect spelling and/or different legal names.
Results on regional dynamics
32. Figure 3 below shows the results of our analysis of LINZ data. Light blue regions have the same
volume share ordering for the 5 largest firms as nationally (i.e., ANZ, ASB, Westpac, BNZ and
Kiwibank), while blue regions have a different ordering and dark blue regions have a firm outside
of ANZ, ASB, Westpac, BNZ and Kiwibank in the top 5.
33. We observe that, in most land districts (7 out of 12 or close to 60%) the ordering of the five
largest banks differed from national volume shares. Kiwibank’s share is consistently relatively
strong and varies across regions. This indicates there are clear regional variations and provides
further evidence to question a finding of a stable oligopoly across ANZ, ASB, Westpac and BNZ.
34. We found that in Taranaki, TSB has the second largest share of mortgages registered, and that in
Southland, Southland Building Society (SBS) has the third largest share of mortgages registered.
We also found that in Nelson, Nelson Building Society has the sixth largest share of mortgages
registered (at 6%, not far behind Kiwibank’s 8%).
35. We consider this highlights that competition can differ across regions, and suggests that smaller
banks (and even non-banks, in the case of Nelson) are able to exercise increased competitive
pressures in specific market segments or geographies, likely through enhanced brand awareness
and history in that region.
36. We consider that these findings are not consistent with what would be expected under a “stable
oligopoly”. We find that volume shares vary across geographies, suggesting there is no clear or
consistent focal point across geographies. Instead, we observe different competitive dynamics at
play in different regions, suggesting that the market structure is not stable.
37. In addition, we consider this to be consistent with the results of our VAR results for mortgages
above, which finds that other banks impact the advertised rates of ANZ, ASB, Westpac, BNZ and
Kiwibank. It is possible that regional variations in the intensity of competition impact the
competitive strategies of ANZ, ASB, Westpac, BNZ and Kiwibank, and given national strategies,
impact headline rates.
Public Version | The extent of competition for personal banking products
21
Figure 3: Estimated regional volume share of registered mortgages from 1 January 2023 to 6 December 2023
Source: Deloitte Access Economics analysis of LINZ data. Note that we have mapped LINZ land districts onto regional council areas, and therefore results for
Northland and Auckland, Waikato and Bay of Plenty, Wellington and Manawatu, and Nelson and Tasman are presented as combined as LINZ land districts group
these regions together.
Public Version | The extent of competition for personal banking products
22
Price matching in the context of variable price leadership and patterns may be
competition at work
38. The Commission notes that price competition is sporadic between major banks and that it is
often focussed on matching competitors’ rates rather than beating them.
48
We agree that price
matching, in certain settings, can act to soften competition. The intuition is that price matching
removes the incentive to undercut prices in the first place, as it eliminates any potential gains
from the price cut as competitors will quickly respond by matching any changes in price.
39. However, it is important to consider the wider context within which price matching is occurring.
For example, price matching may be a way of credibly signalling to consumers that a firm is low-
priced, with the credibility of this signal being assured by vigilance of informed consumers. This
may especially be the case where the optimal price may vary across firms (in this case, the
optimal interest rates across a wide variety of lending and deposit products).
49
40. More generally, it may be the case that the price matching observed by the Commission is
competition at work.
50
Banks offer a wide variety of products across lending and deposit
products. The competitive strategy of a bank for any particular product may depend on factors
such as the consumer mix over products and wholesale funding considerations. Pricing often can
reflect implementation of an overall risk management strategy to:
40.1. Limit maturity risk across products (i.e., too much repricing at the same time). For
example, a bank may be exposed to a large proportion of consumers on 1-year products.
A strategy to diversify consumer mix and risk over products is to price more aggressively
across longer tenured mortgage products.
51
40.2. Be used as a means to manage interest rate exposure for those banks without
sophisticated Treasury functions.
41. We consider the evidence of no price leadership among ANZ, ASB, Westpac, BNZ and Kiwibank
and the varying and dynamic causal relationship we find across advertised mortgage and lending
rates and regions, to be reflective of the varying competitive strategies at play for personal
banking services at any one point in time. As noted previously, this variability extends to
effective interest rates charged on new lending to owner-occupiers, with weak correlation
between these effective rates and associated headline rates.
52
42. Seen in this light, price matching behaviour could be characterised as ensuring a bank is pricing
competitively and signalling to consumers that it is low-priced. The presence of price matching
in this context may also explain the Commission’s observation that market shares appear
relatively stable.
53
That is, price matching serves to limit the duration and extent of any
competitive advantage from the reduction of rates for lending products and an increase in rates
for deposit products.
Personal banking products are homogenous, but only to a degree
43. The Commission’s preliminary view is that personal banking services are largely homogenous,
and that competition between major banks seems to be strongest for certain focal services such
as fixed rate home loans and term deposits.
54
48
Commerce Commission “Personal banking services market study – Draft report” (21 March 2024) at [2.46] and [2.47].
49
See, for example, Sridar Moorthy and Ralph A Winter “Price-matching guarantees” (2006) 37(2) The RAND Journal of Economics 449.
50
We note that in the case of the “green home loan top-up” offers considered by the Commission, the interest rate on most the offerings is
0% and that, over time, banks iteratively improved their offerings by expanding what the top-up can cover and maximum value, rather than
simply matching the first product offered by Kiwibank see Commerce Commission “Personal banking services market study – Draft report”
(21 March 2024) at [Figure 2.4]
51
The Commission notes such a dynamic as well see Commerce Commission “Personal banking services market study Draft report” (21
March 2024) at [4.43]. Other considerations noted include the need to balance growth across lending and deposit portfolios and the ability to
service high volumes of new customers.
52
Ibid, at [Footnote 285].
53
Ibid, at [2.39.1].
54
Ibid, at [2.39.6].
Public Version | The extent of competition for personal banking products
23
44. We agree that personal banking services offered across banks are fundamentally the same.
However, we consider there are important degrees of variation across pricing, product
characteristics and quality dimensions for products such as fixed rate home loans and term
deposits, that bring about a degree of differentiation.
Non-price competition is a driver of consumer choice
45. As the Commission notes: “…with consumers having diverse needs and preferences, non-price
aspects of competition are important considerations for consumers, with research showing that
some consumers are willing to pay more for quality and services”.
55
46. The Commission also notes that Major banks compete on non-price measures, such as a range
of products, services, perception of trust and security, digital capabilities and brand awareness
to meet these needs”; and “Smaller providers also focus on implementing strong non-price
offerings to drive customer growth”.
56
47. As we have previously noted, non-price factors are an important dimension in driving consumer
choice and competitive responses across banks. For instance, a decrease in advertised rates by a
competitor may be met by advertising to emphasise non-price factors, rather than in a
movement in advertised price.
57
The Commission has noted non-price initiatives may be
employed in an effort to minimise volume impacts if a firms home loan interest rates are above
its competitors
58
and Verian survey evidence indicates that for those who have not considered
switching, satisfaction with their current provider is a reason for not considering switching.
59
48. While at its core, personal banking services offer the same service to consumers, the emphasis
on non-price factors, such as service quality, sustainability and digital apps adds differentiation
to products being offered by banks. This adds variability to products that are functionally the
same (e.g., fixed rate mortgages or term deposits), decreasing the comparability between such
products. Importantly, optimal pricing may differ between banks for functionally similar
products, depending on the degree of non-price investment or associated expenditure.
Discretionary discounts also add a degree of differentiation and
reduces price transparency
49. Fundamentally, capital markets impact on pricing for lending and deposit products in New
Zealand. As a small open economy, New Zealand is subject to movements in capital markets
overseas, as well as monetary and fiscal policy locally. The consequence of this is that wholesale
cost benchmarks, such as the Official Cash Rate (OCR), the 90-Day Bank Bill or swap rates,
provide an important input to pricing. Further transparency is provided, as noted by the
Commission, across headline interest rates via interest.co.nz, volume or market share
information, and profitability information via the Reserve Bank dashboard.
60
50. Due to New Zealand being a small open economy, banks may use offshore markets as external
funding sources. This means that banks do not fund at wholesale interest rates as they have to
pay a credit spread above them. The implication of this is that funding costs above wholesale
interest rates fluctuate due to the need to go to offshore markets.
61
55
Ibid, at [2.55].
56
Ibid, at [2.55].
57
Deloitte Access Economics “Personal home loans: Price responsiveness as one dimension of assessing competition” (1 December 2023) at
[11.2].
58
Commerce Commission “Personal banking services market study – Draft report” (21 March 2024) at [4.87].
59
Verian “Personal banking services market study – Research report” (February 2024) at 32.
60
Commerce Commission “Personal banking services market study – Draft report” (21 March 2024) at [4.94]. However, as we discuss in more
detail below, we consider there are other limits to transparency in headline rates for personal banking services. We find that there is no real
price leader at any one point in time and differing and dynamic pricing relationships between banks mortgage and term deposit products. We
consider this likely limits the ability for banks to achieve mutually acceptable outcomes.
61
Deloitte Access Economics “Personal banking services: Consumer switching, conditions of entry and expansion, profitability and innovation
A report for BNZ” (7 September 2023) at [123 127].
Public Version | The extent of competition for personal banking products
24
51. However, the presence of discretionary discounts is likely to add a degree of differentiation for
personal banking services and reduce price transparency. As the ACT has recently observed,
“[t]he widespread publication by the Major Banks of their standard variable rates for mortgages
provides significant price transparency, and changes in their standard variable rates generally
follow changes in the cash rate, which serves as a “focal point” for price adjustments
62
,
however discretionary discounts necessarily detract from price transparency. In particular:
63
51.1. The use of unpublished discretionary discounts necessarily detracts from price
transparency. As found by the Commission, 50% to 60% of all home loans are based on
discretionary discounts.
64
51.2. While banks can monitor and take into account market intelligence that they may glean
from brokers as to discretionary discounts being offered by rivals, this falls well short of
the immediacy and objectivity of published prices, such as the prices prominently posted
on signboards at petrol stations or by airlines on their websites.
65
51.3. The impact of the increasing use of brokers on price transparency is likely to be more
acute for borrowers than banks, as brokers are likely to press for larger discretionary
discounts when negotiating with banks, tending to overstate rather than understate the
availability and magnitude of comparative discretionary discounts.
66
52. We further note that the Commission found no real price leadership for effective interest rates
on new lending to owner-occupiers and a degree of variation between these rates and headline
rates. In particular, the Commission found:
67
52.1. That there was no one provider that was consistently offering best in market interest
rates (nor consistently offering the highest-in-market agreed interest rates).
52.2. A weak correlation between relative headline interest rates and relative observed
average interest rates on new lending across banks:
68
Our analysis of monthly home lending data provided by banks and headline interest rate data from
interest.co.nz found correlations between banks' relative monthly average headline and agreed interest rates
of around 0.25 to 0.40 among the major banks and Kiwibank.
53. We consider the degree of differentiation, and therefore lack of price transparency, is likely to
be increased by the varying nature of discretionary discounting observed for personal banking
services in New Zealand and the weak correlation between headline and effective rates for new
owner-occupier home lending.
54. However, we do acknowledge that a weak correlation between headline and effective rates is
also likely to dampen demand side pressures, as it is likely to increase search costs for
consumers looking to compare personal banking products between banks.
A wider review of evidence suggests Kiwibank is more of a competitive constraint
than found by the Commission
55. The Commission’s preliminary view is that competition for personal banking services is
characterised by a stable oligopoly of ANZ, ASB, Westpac and BNZ with no maverick to disrupt
them, and that there is a second tier of smaller banks, Non-bank Deposit Takers (NBDTs) and
other non-bank lenders.
69
The Commission considers Kiwibank as sitting between these two
62
Applications by Australia and New Zealand Banking Group Limited and Suncorp Group Limited [2024] ACompT 1 at [456].
63
Ibid, at [457] and [460].
64
Commerce Commission “Personal banking services market study – Draft report” (21 March 2024) at [4.26].
65
Applications by Australia and New Zealand Banking Group Limited and Suncorp Group Limited [2024] ACompT 1 at [457].
66
Ibid, at [460].
67
Commerce Commission “Personal banking services market study – Draft report” (21 March 2024), at [4.59].
68
Ibid, at [Footnote 285].
69
Ibid, at [2.22].
Public Version | The extent of competition for personal banking products
25
tiers of providers and that, while it provides some constraint on ANZ, ASB, Westpac and BNZ, it
is not a disrupter of the stable oligopoly.
70
56. As discussed further below, we consider there are regulatory conditions of entry and expansion
that do make it difficult for banks, including Kiwibank and smaller banks, to enter and expand in
personal banking services. These conditions interact with the economies of scale and scope for
personal banking services. We consider these factors play a large role in explaining the relatively
stable market shares observed by the Commission and observed levels of profitability.
71
57. However, a review of the available evidence suggests, in our view, that competition for personal
banking services is more nuanced and effective than a two-tier market, with a stable oligopoly at
the first-tier, smaller providers in the second-tier, and Kiwibank “stuck in the middle”.
Kiwibank has been winning market share off ANZ, ASB, Westpac and
BNZ
58. As the Commission notes, Kiwibank has increased its share of supply since entering the market
in 2002
72
and its loan portfolio has performed strongly in recent years, consistently returning
higher growth (in percentage terms), than ANZ, ASB, Westpac and BNZ, albeit off a lower base
and at a sacrifice of returns.
73
The Commission further notes that a major bank considers
Kiwibank’s position as the “main default alternative to the main banks”
74
and that Kiwibank’s
pricing is a constraint on ANZ, ASB, Westpac and BNZ’s pricing across mortgages and deposit
products.
75
59. Despite these features, the Commission does not consider Kiwibank to be a significant constraint
to ANZ, ASB, Westpac and BNZ and that it sits between the two-tiers in the market.
76
Part of the
reason the Commission reached this conclusion appears to be due to the weight given to
Kiwibank’s current smaller share of the market or share of total banking assets, relative to ANZ,
ASB, Westpac and BNZ.
77
60. We would note that market shares, or share of total assets, are not in themselves a complete
indicator of a competitive constraint or otherwise. A wider range of factors need to be
considered to make this assessment.
78
Our analysis suggests that Kiwibank is more of a
constraint than that found by the Commission when considering a wider range of factors.
60.1. The extent to which a competitor has grown recently, over and above market growth, is
an important indicator of the competitive constraint it provides. In simple terms,
proportionally higher growth than market indicates a competitor is successfully winning
market share off competitors, likely despite competitive responses from those
competitors.
60.2. As the Commission has noted, this is true of Kiwibank. The relatively higher growth of
Kiwibank’s home loan portfolio is reflected in Figure 4, which measures the proportional
change in value share for reported housing loans available under the Reserve Bank of
New Zealand (RBNZ) Financial Strength Dashboard.
70
Ibid, at [4.53].
71
We discuss the impact of regulatory conditions of entry and expansion on profitability in more detail below.
72
Commerce Commission “Personal banking services market study – Draft report” (21 March 2024) at [2.23.1] .
73
Ibid, at [4.50].
74
Ibid, at [4.49].
75
Ibid, at [4.30.2] and [5.38].
76
Ibid, at [4.53].
77
See, for example, Ibid, at [4.48].
78
This is similar to the view the Commerce Commission takes in relation to market share and concentration measures when assessing
mergers and acquisitions see Commerce Commission “Mergers and acquisition guidelines” (May 2022) at [3.53].
Public Version | The extent of competition for personal banking products
26
Figure 4: Proportional change in value share Asset quality Housing Loans series (percentage change, June 2018
to December 2023)
79
Source: Deloitte Access Economics analysis of RBNZ data on housing loans under the Asset quality housing loans series. Blue indicates a D-SIB bank. Bank of
Baroda, Heartland,
80
Rabobank, Bank of China, Bank of India, China Construction Bank and ICBC are not shown but were included in value share calculations.
Value share only includes registered banks.
60.3. Proportionally higher growth for Kiwibank is also evident for deposits, as measured by
the value of deposits held by banks, as demonstrated by Figure 5 below.
Figure 5: Proportional change in value of deposits on balance sheet (percentage change, June 2018 to December
2023)
Source: Deloitte Access Economics analysis of RBNZ data on value of deposits on balance sheets. Blue indicates a D-SIB bank. Bank of Baroda, Heartland,
81
Rabobank, Bank of China, Bank of India, China Construction Bank and ICBC are not shown but were included in value share calculations. Value share only includes
registered banks.
60.4. Our findings when considering relative changes in value and volume shares are also
supported by the Commission’s review of a “broader evidence base” (such as internal
strategy and pricing documents), from which they concluded that Kiwibank’s pricing does
provide “some constraint on the major banks”.
82
Taken together, we consider these
results suggest that Kiwibank is having a growing competitive impact on the market.
79
We note this chart differs from Figure 2 in Deloitte Access Economics “Personal home loans: Price responsiveness as one dimension of
assessing competition” (1 December 2023), as this Figure uses the Asset quality housing loans series data from RBNZ.
80
Heartland is not shown because we understand them to have only substantively re-entered the provision of conventional home loans in
2020. They were included in calculations.
81
Heartland is not shown to be consistent with the Figure above but was included in calculations.
82
Commerce Commission “Personal banking services market study – Draft report” (21 March 2024) at [4.52] and [4.53].
-6%
-4%
-2%
0%
2%
4%
6%
8%
10%
12%
Kiwibank SBS ANZ Co-op Westpac ASB BNZ TSB
-10%
-5%
0%
5%
10%
15%
20%
25%
Kiwibank SBS ANZ Co-op Westpac ASB BNZ TSB
Public Version | The extent of competition for personal banking products
27
60.5. The Commission also notes that, in the case of term deposits, “the major banks and
Kiwibank tend to closely monitor each other’s interest rates”.
83
The Verian Survey evidence and LINZ data suggest Kiwibank is a close
competitor
61. Another factor to consider is how close consumers view competitors to be in a market. The
closer two competitors are considered, the more of a constraint each imposes on the other, as
there is an increased likelihood consumers may switch should the price be increased or quality
degraded.
84
62. The Commission’s consumer research, undertaken on its behalf by Verian, find the following:
62.1. 95% of consumers surveyed use either ANZ, ASB, Westpac, BNZ or Kiwibank for at least
one product. 22% use Westpac, 20% BNZ and 19% Kiwibank.
85
62.2. 92% of consumers surveyed use either ANZ, ASB, Westpac, BNZ, or Kiwibank as their
main bank. 19% use ASB, 17% use Westpac, 14% use BNZ and 12% use Kiwibank.
86
62.3. 88% of consumers only considered ANZ, ASB, Westpac, BNZ and Kiwibank when first
choosing providers.
87
62.4. 58% of consumers would only consider ANZ, ASB, Westpac, BNZ and Kiwibank if
switching in the future.
88
63. We consider this evidence, taken as a whole, suggests that consumers currently see Kiwibank as
a closer competitor or alternative to ANZ, ASB, Westpac and BNZ. This observed closeness sits in
contrast to the Commission’s preliminary view that Kiwibank is not a significant constraint to
ASB, Westpac and BNZ.
64. We also analysed the closeness of Kiwibank to ANZ, ASB, Westpac or BNZ based on the LINZ data
between 1 January 2023 and 6 December 2023. The analysis suggests Kiwibank is close to either
BNZ or Westpac. This is in contrast to the distance implied by the current lending portfolio of
Kiwibank when compared to BNZ’s, which is less than half.
89
65. At a national level, BNZ’s share was the 4
th
highest and stood at 14%, while Kiwibank’s share was
5
th
highest, at 9%. This is largely true at a regional level (also see Figure 3). For instance:
83
Ibid, at [5.38].
84
This is the approach the Commission takes to assessing competition in differentiated product markets - Commerce Commission “Personal
banking services market study Draft report” (21 March 2024) at [3.72].
85
Verian “Personal banking services market study – Research report” (February 2024) at 13.
86
Ibid, at 15.
87
Ibid, at 35.
88
Ibid, at 45.
89
Commerce Commission “Personal banking services market study – Draft report” (21 March 2024) at [4.48].
Public Version | The extent of competition for personal banking products
28
Figure 6: Estimated regional volume share of registered mortgages of Kiwibank and its next closest rival from 1
January 2023 to 6 December 2023
Source: Deloitte Access Economics analysis of LINZ data
65.1. At a regional level Kiwibank’s volume shares were 5
th
highest with either BNZ or Westpac
being the next closest rival with 4
th
highest volume shares, as illustrated by Figure 6
above. The exception to this is the Southland and Taranaki regions. In the Southland
region, BNZ’s share was the 5
th
highest and stood at 10%, while Kiwibank’s share was 6
th
highest, at 6%. In the Taranaki region, Westpac’s share was the 5
th
highest and stood at
12%, while Kiwibank’s share was 6
th
highest, at 7%.
65.2. The relative closeness in lending volume shares between Kiwibank and its next closest
competitor is also highlighted in Figure 6. For all regions, with the exception of the Otago
region, the difference between Kiwibank’s volume shares and the volume shares of its
next closest competitor is less than half.
90
65.3. We further note that overall Kiwibank’s volume share is at least 50% of either BNZ or
Westpac at a regional level. This is relatively higher when compared to Macquarie in
Australia, which was found to have a market share of a third of the next closest
competitor. Both the Commission and the ACT considered this sufficient to support a
characterisation of Macquarie as a “maverick” and a disrupter.
91
90
It is only in the Otago region where Kiwibank’s market share (6%) is less than half of its next closest competitor, in this case, BNZ (13%).
91
Commerce Commission “Personal banking services market study – Draft report” (21 March 2024) at [2.70].
15%
13%
12%
14%
12%
14%
9%
9%
9%
9%
13%
7%
0%
5%
10%
15%
20%
North Auckland South Auckland Wellington Hawkes Bay Gisborne Taranaki
North Island
13%
14%
11%
12%
10%
13%
11%
8%
8%
10%
6%
6%
0%
5%
10%
15%
Canterbury Marlborough Nelson Westland Southland Otago
South Island
Westpac BNZ Kiwibank
Public Version | The extent of competition for personal banking products
29
Market concentration for personal banking has decreased of late
66. We consider that the range of factors identified (i.e., the variability in pricing and pricing
relationships across a number of products and banks, the constraint that Kiwibank provides on
ANZ, ASB, Westpac and BNZ and growth of Kiwibank above “system” levels and the increasing
switching recently) is contributing to the decline in concentration for personal banking services
seen of late.
67. While classical measures of market concentration, such as the C4 or C5 concentration indices
which measure the market share held by the top four or five largest firms, indicate very high
market concentration for personal banking services, the more nuanced Herfindahl-Hirschman
Index (HHI) suggest concentration is “moderate”.
92
68. The HHI is calculated as the sum of the square of the market share of every firm in the market,
meaning it captures concentration dynamics at play outside of the largest four or five firms in a
market. A value between 1,500 and 2,500 indicates modest concentration and more than 2,500
reflects high market concentration.
93
69. The econometrics paper finds that concentration as measured by the HHI ranges from between
1,930 to 2,080 varying over time and by market share measure (total deposits, total loans and
total assets), sitting at around 1,950 at the end of the sample period.
70. These results suggest that concentration is moderate (being well within the 1,500 to 2,500
band) but also dynamic over time, having decreased between 2016 and 2022.
94
This is
consistent with our findings from mortgage registrations volume shares in Figure 3, which
demonstrates that the volume shares of Kiwibank has risen over this period while those of ANZ,
ASB and Westpac have decreased slightly (and BNZ’s has remained stable).
Personal banking services has been subject to periods of uncertainty and change
71. In the Draft Report, the Commission comments that there is “a lack of market volatility” and that
this, among other factors, is “consistent with the conditions for coordination”.
95
72. While headline indicators for the New Zealand sector have been relatively stable over time (for
example, the New Zealand sector was relatively unimpacted by recent banking events in the
United States and Europe), this is likely a result of New Zealand having one of the highest capital
requirements globally.
96
73. These stable headline indicators detract from the fact that personal banking services have been
subject to periods of extensive volatility and uncertainty, notably the Global Financial Crisis
(GFC) and the COVID-19 pandemic. These periods of uncertainty not only had an impact on
competition for personal banking services during the crisis, but in the case of the GFC also had a
lasting impact.
The GFC exposed how risky the sector can be and caused a permanent
shift in funding preferences
74. The 2007-2008 GFC was characterised by offshore capital markets seizing up virtually overnight,
beginning in the United States and rapidly transmitting through the rest of the global financial
system. Several major global financial institutions, such as Lehman Brothers, Fannie Mae,
Freddie Mac and the Royal Bank of Scotland (RBS), amongst others, were either liquidated or
bailed out by central banks as a result.
92
Professor Dimitris Margaritis & Dr Maryam Hasannasab “Market power in banking: A study of New Zealand banks” (March 2024) at 6-7.
93
Ibid, at 6-7.
94
Ibid, at 7.
95
Commerce Commission “Personal banking services market study – Draft report” (21 March 2024) at [2.67].
96
PwC for the New Zealand Bankers’ Associated “International comparability of the capital ratios of New Zealand’s major banks” (October
2017) at page 22, available at https://www.nzba.org.nz/wp-content/uploads/2017/11/PWC-capital-ratios-study.pdf
Public Version | The extent of competition for personal banking products
30
75. Although no New Zealand banks were bailed out or liquidated during the GFC, there was
significant concern that with large institutions overseas failing, it was a very real prospect
domestically. Short-term offshore debt funding represented approximately half of New
Zealand’s banks’ balance sheets at the time of the GFC.
97
76. As a result of the GFC, regulators required banks to shift their funding composition away from
shorter-term offshore wholesale debt funding sources to onshore deposits, which are typically
considered to be a more stable source of funding. As we have previously observed, this had a
lasting impact on the spreads between the rates on lending products and funding sources.
98
Figure 7: 6-month term deposit, floating mortgage and short-term wholesale rates (2000 2024)
Source: RBNZ
77. Pre-GFC, the 6-month term deposit rate and 90-bank bill yield tracked very closely to each other with
the 6-month term deposit typically being lower than the 90-bank bill yield. Post-GFC, this relationship
was reversed, and a wedge opened up between the two. This was likely driven by the reduced ability to
rely on wholesale funding and an increase in demand from New Zealand banks for onshore funding in
the form of retail term deposits. The events that unfolded overseas saw increased pressure from
investors, regulators and customers for banks to favour stable, longer-term funding sources such as
domestic term deposits.
78. As discussed further below, post the COVID-19 pandemic the demand for retail term deposits by New
Zealand banks decreased and the supply of money substantially increased. This resulted in more money
within the system that found its way into deposits, therefore, banks pricing strategy did not need to be
as aggressive to raise deposits. This is the reverse of post-GFC environment. This reversal is only just
beginning to normalise, whereby term deposit rates are greater than wholesale funding rates.
Periods of less intense competition coincide with heightened periods of uncertainty
and external policy interventions
79. The Commission’s preliminary view is that competition for personal banking services is sporadic.
It notes there are periods when competition is more intense with lower margins, but other
times where competition is less intense. It observes that it is particularly true of home loans and
term deposits.
99
80. The Commission’s view appears to be based on evidence of measures of market power between
2016 and 2023 and growth relative to lending system growth. In particular:
97
Jason Wong (RBNZ) “Bank funding the change in composition and pricing” (June 2012) at 17.
98
Deloitte Access Economics “Personal banking services: Consumer switching, conditions of entry and expansion, profitability and innovation
A report for BNZ” (7 September 2023) at [178] [181].
99
Commerce Commission “Personal banking services market study – Draft report” (21 March 2024) at [2.39.2].
0%
2%
4%
6%
8%
10%
12%
2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018 2020 2022 2024
6-month Term Deposit Floating Mortgage 90-day Bank Bill Yield
Public Version | The extent of competition for personal banking products
31
80.1. Patterns of growth of ANZ, ASB, Westpac, BNZ and Kiwibank, relative to system growth
for lending, and in particular, growth broadly in line with system growth between 2020
and 2022.
100
80.2. On an estimated Lerner Index for loans, which is a measure of the spread between price
and marginal costs divided by price. The estimated Lerner Index indicates moderate
market power, as it sits above 0 for most banks. The estimated Lerner Index notably
increases in 2020 to 2021, before appearing to fall again in 2022
101
, indicating a potential
reduction in the extent of competition during 2020 to 2021.
80.3. On an estimated Panzar-Rosse-H-Statistic (H-Statistic). Values between 0 and 1 are
generally interpreted as indicative of imperfect competition. A H-Statistic of less than 0
can be expected under a profit-maximising monopoly. Similar to the Lerner Index,
moderate market power is found, with the H-statistic falling closer towards 0 from 2020
to 2021, before increasing again.
102
81. While it is possible that growth in line with system growth and increases in measures of market
power are symptomatic of sporadic competition, we consider there are other plausible
explanations for these trends.
Growth at system levels coincides with the COVID-19 pandemic
82. COVID-19 was associated with strict lockdowns in New Zealand, stifling economic activity.
103
It is
plausible that banks’ competitive strategy between 2020 and 2021 was to consolidate or defend
market positions. In addition, banks strategy at the time may have been to support existing
customers with interest rate relief and other support measures, rather than aggressively
competing for new customers.
104
This would explain the relative lack of volatility in growth,
relative to system growth during this period. Figure 8 below provides a view on the annual home
lending growth for ANZ, ASB, Westpac, BNZ and Kiwibank as a ratio of overall home lending
growth in New Zealand. As Figure 8 below demonstrates, the period of ‘pulling back’ (i.e.,
growth at system levels) coincides to a large extent around the uncertainty caused by COVID-19
and associated lockdowns.
100
Ibid, at [4.13.2]. and [Figure 4.3].
101
Dimitris Margaritis and Maryam Hasannasab “Market power in banking: A study of New Zealand banks” (March 2024) at 16 and [Figure
11].
102
Ibid, at 17-18 and [Figure 12].
103
Department of the Prime Minister and Cabinet “Timeline of significant COVID-19 events” (October 2023), available at
https://www.dpmc.govt.nz/sites/default/files/2023-10/pr-timeline-significant-events-activities.pdf
104
See, for example, ANZ “Response to COVID-19 Pandemic” (30 April 2020), available at
https://www.anz.com/content/dam/anzcom/shareholder/ANZ-Covid-19-response-30%20April-2020.pdf
Public Version | The extent of competition for personal banking products
32
Figure 8: Annual home lending growth as a multiple of system growth for ANZ, ASB, Westpac, BNZ and Kiwibank
Source: Deloitte Access Economics analysis of RBNZ data.
83. The grey box represents the period under which New Zealand was subject to the Alert Level
System
105
(and, therefore, when COVID-19 uncertainty was at its peak). We do not, therefore,
consider it appropriate to draw inferences from this period about the nature of competition.
84. Figure 8 also illustrates that growth relative to system has become more volatile since the
uncertainty associated with the COVID-19 pandemic has largely subsided.
The impacts of policy intervention
85. During this time, fears that the pandemic would induce a severe global recession frightened
global financial markets and, much like the GFC, liquidity became a key concern for New Zealand
banks. However, the RBNZ quickly flooded the New Zealand financial system with liquidity
through unconventional monetary policy tools such as the Large Scale Asset Purchase
programme (LSAP)
106
, Funding for Lending (FLP)
107
and Term Lending Facility programme
(TLF).
108
86. As the RBNZ noted in its November 2023 Financial Stability Report, the FLP provided a low-cost
marginal source for long-term stable funding for banks, increasing banks settlement balances
and putting downward pressure on competition for deposits. The LSAP created deposits upon
the RBNZ purchasing bonds from the secondary market. The RBNZ observed that the effect of
this was that “the high level of liquid assets in the banking system meant that banks could
comfortably operate with a higher share of their deposits kept at call”.
109
This is demonstrated
by the fall in premiums on term deposits over call deposits.
105
Department of the Prime Minister and Cabinet “Timeline of significant COVID-19 events” (October 2023), available at
https://www.dpmc.govt.nz/sites/default/files/2023-10/pr-timeline-significant-events-activities.pdf
106
RBNZ “Large scale asset purchase programme” (23 March 2022), available at Large scale asset purchase programme - Reserve Bank of
New Zealand - Te Pūtea Matua (rbnz.govt.nz).
107
RBNZ “More monetary stimulus provided” (11 November 2020), available at More monetary stimulus provided - Reserve Bank of New
Zealand - Te Pūtea Matua (rbnz.govt.nz).
108
RBNZ “Longer-term funding to support business lending” (2 April 2020), available at Longer-term funding to support business lending -
Reserve Bank of New Zealand - Te Pūtea Matua (rbnz.govt.nz).
109
RBNZ “Financial Stability Report” (November 2023) at 39.
0.00
0.50
1.00
1.50
2.00
Mar-19 Jun-19 Sep-19 Dec-19 Mar-20 Jun-20 Sep-20 Dec-20 Mar-21 Jun-21 Sep-21 Dec-21 Mar-22 Jun-22 Sep-22 Dec-22 Mar-23 Jun-23 Sep-23
Ratio
System ANZ ASB Westpac BNZ Kiwibank
Auckland and
Upper Hauraki
Alert Level 3
(21 September
2021)
Upper Northland
Alert Level 3 (2
November 2021)
Nationwide
Alert Level 4 (25
March 2020)
Nationwide Alert
Level 2, Auckland
Alert Level 3 (14
Feb 2021)
Public Version | The extent of competition for personal banking products
33
Figure 9: Premium on 6-month term deposit compared to on-call savings and term deposits share of total
deposits
Source: RBNZ
87. As the RBNZ observes, during this period, banks have experienced higher than average net
interest margins (NIMs), as the interest income earned on their assets has grown faster than the
interest costs paid on their funding. As shown by Figure 10, the increase in NIMs was not
because mortgage and term deposit rates did not move downward together when the RBNZ
introduced policies to support liquidity (they both bottom-out in mid-early 2021), it was due to
the relative size of the moves. Figure 10 shows how the spread between the advertised 1-year
mortgage rates and 1-year term deposit rates moved during this period relative to the average
spread pre-2020.
Figure 10: Spread between advertised 1-year mortgage rates and 1-year term deposit rates
Source: Deloitte Access Economics analysis of RBNZ data
88. The RBNZ expects over time, as demand for funding increases, that banks are likely to compete
more aggressively for deposits, resulting in higher overall funding costs. This could see NIMs
decline closer to their long-term averages and could put downward pressure on bank profits.
110
89. The elevated levels of measures of market power observed by the Commission between 2020
and 2021 coincide with the impacts of LSAP and FLP discussed above. We therefore consider
that the higher measures of market power are likely to be explained by these policy
110
RBNZ “Financial Stability Report” (November 2023) at 41.
0.0
10.0
20.0
30.0
40.0
50.0
60.0
70.0
80.0
0
50
100
150
200
250
2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023
6-month term deposit premium to on-call savings Term deposit share of total savings deposits
Premium (bps) Term deposits share of deposits (%)
0
0.5
1
1.5
2
2.5
3
2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023 2024
%
1-year Spread Pre-2020 Avg Spread
Public Version | The extent of competition for personal banking products
34
interventions, rather than an episode demonstrating that there is sporadic nature of
competition between banks.
Switching for mortgages appears to be increasing
Impediments to switching are generally perceived, rather than actual
90. We acknowledge that there is some consumer inertia and consumer switching costs for personal
banking services in New Zealand.
111
However, as noted by the Commission, this is a feature of
personal banking markets worldwide, with this trend recognised in Australia for retail deposits
and home loans and more generally in the United Kingdom.
112
We do not consider this to be an
unexpected result in the New Zealand context.
91. We also note that ‘inertia’ is not the only consideration at play when it comes to consumer
switching. We consider it is also important to consider:
91.1. The “choice process” framework under which switching decisions are made. This is an
iterative process under which consumers assess switching decisions.
113
91.2. The extent to which consumer decisions not to switch are driven by high levels of
satisfaction. For example, Verian found that the most common reason for not
considering switching is “[h]appy where I am/no problems”, ranging from 56% to 69% of
respondents depending on product.
114
92. Regarding the impediments to consumers switching personal banking products from one
provider to another, we consider it is important to note the distinction between actual and
perceived impediments to switching.
92.1. The Verian survey finds that those who did switch found the process easier than those
who considered switching but did not. For those that switched 62% reported the process
to be easy or very easy.
92.2. However, for those that considered switching but did not, only 36% believed the process
to be easy or very easy.
115
93. These results suggest that the process may be easier than expected and provide evidence that
that the perceived difficulty associated with switching may be creating a greater impediment
than actual difficulty experienced with switching.
94. That is not to say that actual impediments to switching do not exist. The Verian survey finds that
a third who considered switching found it easy, but still did not follow through, there were
impediments for them being around uncertainty or the availability of better offers. For those
that found the process difficult, the majority found the process took too much time, effort or
admin, while one in five had difficulty accessing information or help.
116
Despite perceived impediments, there has been increased switching of
late
95. We note that there is also evidence to suggest that switching is increasing for some products in
the sector.
95.1. Analysis of the RBNZ data on new residential mortgage lending by purpose finds that in
the first quarter of 2024 approximately 20% of new residential mortgage lending was
111
Commerce Commission “Personal banking services market study – Draft report” (21 March 2024) at [8.4]
112
Ibid, at [8.11] and [8.12]
113
Deloitte Access Economics “Personal banking services: Consumer switching, conditions of entry and expansion, profitability and innovation
A report for BNZ” (7 September 2023) at [27].
114
Verian “Personal banking services market study Research report” (February 2024) at 32.
115
Ibid, at 28.
116
Ibid, at 28.
Public Version | The extent of competition for personal banking products
35
due to consumers switching home loans to another provider. This is an increase relative
to the pre-COVID-19 period, as demonstrated by Figure 11 below.
95.2. The Verian survey findings point out that home loans are the most commonly switched
product
117
and highlights that switching of a home loan to a bank often drives the
switching of other products as well.
118
Figure 11: Changes in provider of home loans as a percentage of total new home lending for all purposes
Source: Deloitte Access Economics analysis of RBNZ data
95.3. The Verian survey also finds that for those who considered switching but did not, the
most commonly considered product for switching were home loans.
119
As noted in
previous submissions, workable competition in the market is supported through the
ability to switch even if the consumer does not follow through with the action.
120
95.4. The Commission recognises that multi-banking (consumers who have personal banking
relationships with two or more providers) has increased over time due to the reduction
in switching barriers.
121
They also indicate that this trend in multi-banking could imply
the competitive advantage of main bank relationship is decreasing.
122
Evidence from [ ]
suggests a similar trend. Indications below are, generally speaking, that a larger
proportion of customers are multihoming within one product type than they were in
2019. This indicates that multihoming, and by extension switching, is increasing over
time.
95.5. Figure 12 to Figure 15 below illustrates the absolute change, from July 2019 to June
2023, in the percentage of consumers that have a personal banking product with one
provider, for example ANZ, who also have another product of the same type with
another provider, for example BNZ. Where other is all providers not listed in the survey
but specified by participants.
117
Ibid, at 19.
118
Ibid, at 20.
119
Ibid, at 24.
120
Deloitte Access Economics “Personal banking services: Consumer switching, conditions of entry and expansion, profitability and innovation
A report for BNZ” (7 September 2023) at [14].
121
Commerce Commission “Personal banking services market study Draft report” (21 March 2024) at [8.13].
122
Ibid, at [2.11].
0%
5%
10%
15%
20%
25%
2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023
Public Version | The extent of competition for personal banking products
36
Figure 12: [ ]
[ ]
Source: [ ]
95.6. Figure 12 above, illustrates for savings accounts multihoming is increasing for most
banks. In particular [ ].
Figure 13: [ ]
[ ]
Source: [ ].
95.7. Similar to savings accounts, in Figure 13, [ ].
95.8. As noted by the Commission, the convenience of having a transaction account and a
savings account with the same provider may be important to some consumers.
123
Therefore, it is unsurprising that the increase in multihoming, and by extension
switching, follows a similar trend for both transaction accounts and savings accounts.
Figure 14: [ ]
[ ]
Source: [ ].
95.9. [ ]
123
Commerce Commission “Personal banking services market study – Draft report” (21 March 2024) at [5.34].
Public Version | The extent of competition for personal banking products
37
95.10. [ ]
Figure 15: [ ]
[ ]
Source: [ ]
95.11. [ ]
Increased digitalisation and use of brokers is likely to increase
switching
96. Consumer preferences are changing as there is a decreased reliance on physical branches and
increased preference for digital services. As we have previously noted, post COVID-19, digital
channels (i.e., internet and mobile banking) have become more popular and embedded for most
basic banking services. We note that consumer switching is likely to continue to evolve due to
the digitalisation of personal banking services. It is likely to change consumer behaviour and
expectations of the services they receive.
124
97. The Commission observes an increase in the use of mortgage brokers in New Zealand.
125
We
have previously noted, mortgage brokers can make personal banking services more competitive
as they have access to loan products from a range of lenders, therefore enhancing consumers’
knowledge of loan products.
126
This can aid switching via reducing impediments such as search
and switching costs.
98. The importance of brokers in consumer switching of personal banking services was recognised
by the ACT:
127
[T]he use of brokers has led to a reduction in search and switching costs and has facilitated price
competition brokers are an important driver of competition in the home loans market because
they facilitate price transparency for consumers and identify opportunities for repricing and
refinancing.
99. Brokers are a significant source of business for lenders. [ ]
128
124
Deloitte Access Economics “Personal banking services: Consumer switching, conditions of entry and expansion, profitability and innovation
A report for BNZ” (7 September 2023) at [58] and [63.2].
125
Commerce Commission “Personal banking services market study – Draft report” (21 March 2024) at [2.71].
126
Deloitte Access Economics “Personal banking services: Consumer switching, conditions of entry and expansion, profitability and innovation
A report for BNZ” (7 September 2023) at [51].
127
Applications by Australia and New Zealand Banking Group Limited and Suncorp Group Limited [2024] ACompT 1 at [463].
128
[ ]
Public Version | The extent of competition for personal banking products
38
Figure 16: [ ]
[ ]
Source: [ ]
100. The above evidence demonstrates the important role brokers can have in incentivising
consumer switching for home loans and personal banking services more broadly.
There are likely some impediments to entry and expansion, owing to an interaction
of regulatory conditions and economies of scale and scope
Overview of Draft Report findings surrounding impediments to entry
and expansion
101. In the Draft Report the Commission identified that there are high barriers to sustainable new
entry and expansion in personal banking services. For example:
129
101.1. There are significant fixed costs in providing banking services.
101.2. Regulation is a condition of entry but also is an important factor that can directly or
indirectly affect a provider’s ability to expand and grow in the market.
101.3. The Commission finds that the major banks benefit from lower average funding costs
than smaller banks. We note that this may be explained, in part, by the diversity of
funding sources major banks have access to.
101.4. A significant degree of brand recognition and low customer engagement.
Economies of scale and scope as a barrier to entry and expansion
102. New Zealand has a small banking sector when compared to international counterparts. With a
population smaller than Sydney, and fewer than two million residential dwellings, the personal
banking services sector in New Zealand is relatively small. Yet this market supports five larger
bank competitors amongst 27 registered banks as well as 16 registered NBDT and a significant
range of smaller financial entities that are also material competitors across various products and
services.
103. The small scale may naturally limit the nature and the extent of entry and expansion for
personal banking services as there is an inherent trade-off between productive and allocative
efficiency.
130
104. We recognise some conditions to expansion are likely to remain, notwithstanding the reduced
importance of branch networks, recent entry into New Zealand (such as Wise, Dosh, Squirrel
and Simplicity), and the success of Kiwibank increasing its volume share:
129
Commerce Commission “Personal banking services market study – Draft report” (21 March 2024) at [2.20]; [2.20.1] [2.20.4] and [8.21].
130
Deloitte Access Economics “Personal banking services: Consumer switching, conditions of entry and expansion, profitability and innovation
A report for BNZ” (7 September 2023) at [84] to [86].
Public Version | The extent of competition for personal banking products
39
104.1. As the Commission’s Draft Report found, scale is important in personal banking services
because the provision of banking services involves significant fixed costs.
104.2. It is evident that the relevance of economies of scale is not static. Trends in consumer
preferences such as the declining preference for physical retail branches, increasing
preference for digital products and services by consumers, may lessen the extent to
which economies of scale impact entry and expansion.
131
Branch presence is therefore
no longer necessary to compete, and economies of scope is changing in the digital era,
for example, new entrants are not burdened by legacy information technology systems.
104.3. As shown above, Kiwibank’s proportional change in its value share for both home loans
and deposits outweighed any other competitor since 2018.
104.4. Branding and reputation are an important consideration for consumers when choosing
their personal banking services. Our findings suggest although this factor may impose
conditions for entry and expansion, it is not an insurmountable condition. This is due to
the evidence that smaller banks (in terms of balance sheet size), have grown over the
past five years for both deposits and mortgage lending.
132
This is also evidenced in Figure
3 whereby the analysis of regional trends exhibit a regional outperformance of TSB and
SBS relative to their size in the Taranaki and southland regions respectively. We note that
this is in contrast to the findings of the Commission who discuss that the significant
degree of brand recognition in the market for personal banking services is an ongoing
barrier to entry and expansion of smaller providers in the sector.
133
105. Due to the nature of economies of scale and scope in personal banking services, it may be more
effective and disruptive to have a different business model compared to most banks in New
Zealand. For example, Macquarie Bank’s growth can be attributed to its commitment to
delivering strong service through the advisor channel.
134
This strategy was significantly different
to the other major banks in Australia, allowing it to expand in the Australian personal banking
market.
Importance of regulation as a condition of entry and expansion
106. We agree that regulation imposes a direct condition of entry and expansion in the personal
banking services sector. The Commission notes that regulation is the single most important
factor constraining new entry and the ability of existing providers to expand and compete.
135
107. Our analysis finds that there are several supervisory bodies that influence New Zealand banks
and financial institutions. These include but are not limited to: RBNZ, Financial Markets
Authority (FMA), the Commission, Ministry of Business, Innovation and Employment (MBIE) and
the Treasury.
136
The number of supervisory bodies may be generating impediments to entry and
expansion in the sector with conflicting policy goals.
108. It is evident that regulatory factors impose conditions for entry and expansion for personal
banking services and may dampen some aspects of competition. However, it is important to
note that New Zealand’s financial regulatory framework is designed primarily to ensure financial
stability which is paramount given the systemic importance of the banking sector in any
economy. We do note that regulation should ideally be competitively neutral across banks and
other providers where possible, but it is important that the inherent riskiness of a sector
participant is still considered to avoid creating moral hazard problems.
131
Ibid, at [88] and [89].
132
Ibid, at [107].
133
See, for example, Commerce Commission “Personal banking services market study – Draft report” (21 March 2024) at [2.58].
134
Ibid, at [4.128].
135
Ibid, at 159.
136
The Treasury “Regulated parties and key stakeholders”, available at https://www.treasury.govt.nz/information-and-
services/regulation/systems-we-steward/reserve-banks-institutional-regime/regulated-parties-and-key-stakeholders
Public Version | Profitability
40
Profitability
Key points
We do not agree with the Commission’s dismissal of high observed levels of efficiency of larger banks as
a potential explanation for observed levels of profitability. In markets where firms have differing costs,
capacity constraints and efficiency levels, prices and profits are set by the marginal producer. Firms
more efficient than the marginal producer will earn higher than normal returns, even in competitive
markets.
We agree that in a market without impediments to entry and expansion, higher than normal profits
would eventually be expected to be competed away. However, regulatory conditions mean we would
not necessarily expect this to occur for personal banking services. In a market with regulatory conditions
impacting entry and expansion, even if competition is otherwise working well, we would expect those
more efficient firms to continue earning higher returns.
We invite the Commission to consider whether regulatory settings designed to ensure financial stability,
rather than a lack of workable competition between current participants, is fundamentally what
explains the persistency of relatively higher profitability for some banks in New Zealand.
Efficiency, economic profit and the marginal producer
109. In its Draft Report, the Commission identifies that New Zealand banks have relatively low-cost
structures when compared to overseas banks,
137
and that larger New Zealand banks have
relatively low-cost structures when compared to smaller New Zealand banks
138
(noting the
Industrial and Commercial Bank of China (ICBC), China Construction Bank (CCB) and Bank of
China as exceptions). However, while the Commission notes that, under a workably competitive
market, “more efficient firms can extract greater returns”,
139
they would also expect that “the
first tier banks would have competed away profits attributable to their relatively lower cost-to-
income (CTI) ratio”.
140
They also note that in a workably competitive market “we would also
expect to see less efficient firms seeking to capture, and compete away, some of those higher
returns by expanding”.
141
110. In this section, we discuss:
110.1. Why, even under a competitive market, profits attributable to high levels of efficiency
will only be competed away until the marginal firm is earning a normal return.
110.2. Why both accounting and economic efficiency are likely to explain the higher profitability
of ANZ, ASB, Westpac and BNZ.
110.3. Why the observed persistency in relatively higher profitability is likely a consequence of
the regulatory framework in New Zealand designed primarily to ensure financial stability,
given the systemic importance of larger banks to New Zealand’s economy.
137
Commerce Commission “Personal banking services market study – Draft report” (21 March 2024) at [C91].
138
Ibid, at [C92].
139
Ibid, at [C95].
140
Ibid, at [C96].
141
Ibid, at [C97].
Public Version | Profitability
41
New Zealand’s banks are measured to be relatively efficient under
economic and accounting definitions of efficiency
111. As we have previously noted and the Commission finds, New Zealand’s larger banks are
relatively cost efficient when compared to international peers and smaller New Zealand
banks.
142
111.1. Figure 17 shows that (at the industry level) the CTI ratio of New Zealand banks has
consistently sat below the lower quartile of the Commission’s chosen comparator
countries.
111.2. Figure 18 shows that, relative to most smaller banks in New Zealand, ANZ, ASB, BNZ and
Westpac tend to experience lower CTI ratios, suggesting the existence of some form of
economies of scale and/or scope.
Figure 17: Cost-to-income ratio for selected comparison countries
Source: Deloitte Access Economics analysis of World Bank data. Selected countries are the same as those considered by the Commerce Commission.
142
Commerce Commission “Personal banking services market study – Draft report” (21 March 2024) at [6.54] and Deloitte Access Economics
“Personal banking services: Consumer switching, conditions of entry and expansion, profitability and innovation – A report for BNZ” (7
September 2023) at [189] to [198].
0%
50%
100%
150%
200%
250%
2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018 2020
Maximum Upper Quartile Median Lower Quartile Minimum New Zealand
Public Version | Profitability
42
Figure 18: Cost-to-income ratio for New Zealand banks
Source: Deloitte Access Economics analysis of RBNZ Financial Stability Dashboard data. Cost-to-income ratio has been calculated as CTI = Operating Expenses /
Total Income.
143
Other banks are BOB, BOI, CCB, Co-op, Heartland, ICBC, Rabobank, SBS and TSB.
112. While these measures suggest New Zealand’s banks are relatively efficient using accounting
measures, there is a very important distinction between the definitions of accounting and
economic efficiency. While accounting efficiency is usually achieved by minimising a ratio
involving operating costs in the numerator, economic efficiency covers three key components:
112.1. Technical or productive efficiency, achieved where outputs are produced at the least
cost.
112.2. Allocative efficiency, where resources are allocated to the production of outputs in a way
which provides the greatest (economic) benefit relative to (economic) costs.
112.3. Dynamic efficiency, where industries respond over time to changes in technology and
consumer tastes.
113. These are also the three types of efficiency considered by the Commission under its
Authorisation Guidelines.
144
Our discussion will focus on productive efficiency and using the
optimal combination of inputs.
114. In their paper Market Power in Banking: A study of New Zealand banks’ (commissioned by the
Commission) (econometrics paper), Professor Dimitris Margaritis and Dr Maryan Hasannasab (of
the University of Auckland) assessed how efficient New Zealand’s banks are using economic
measures.
115. The econometrics paper considers two measures of efficiency: cost and profit efficiency.
115.1. Cost efficiency was estimated using stochastic frontier analysis (SFA), where total costs
are modelled as a function of outputs and input prices. Cost efficiency is therefore
defined as the distance between a bank’s actual costs and the ‘optimal’ costs predicted
by the frontier.
145
115.2. Profit efficiency was similarly estimated using SFA and allows for identifying
“inefficiencies in banks’ profit generation process, allowing for targeted improvements in
resource allocation, risk management, and operational effectiveness”. In their model,
143
This is consistent with the definition of CTI used by the Commission in its Draft Report and the World Bank in its Global Financial
Development Database. Commerce Commission “Personal banking services market study – Draft report” (21 March 2024) at [C4].
144
Commerce Commission “Authorisation Guidelines” (June 2023) at [63] to [83], available at
https://comcom.govt.nz/__data/assets/pdf_file/0012/91011/Authorisation-Guidelines-June-2023.pdf
145
Professor Dimitris Margaritis & Dr Maryam Hasannasab “Market power in banking: A study of New Zealand banks” (March 2024) at 7-8.
0%
10%
20%
30%
40%
50%
60%
70%
80%
2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023
ANZ ASB BNZ Kiwibank Westpac Other Banks
Public Version | Profitability
43
profit markup is a function of output quantities and input prices, allowing for the
existence of imperfect competition.
146
116. The econometrics paper found that, using both cost and profit measures of economic efficiency,
New Zealand’s banks are efficient.
116.1. They find that “New Zealand banks operate with relatively high cost efficiency, generally
in the 80-90% mark”, and we note that ASB, ANZ, BNZ, Westpac and Kiwibank all have
estimated cost efficiency levels above 90% for the period considered. As the paper notes,
their measure of cost efficiency is made up of both technical efficiency (efficiently
converting the chosen inputs into outputs) and allocative efficiency (using the optimal
combination of inputs).
147
116.2. Similarly, they conclude that the profit efficiency analysis presented “further evidence of
high efficiency levels for New Zealand banks” and that “profit efficiency ranges in the 75-
90% mark for most banks”. We note that profit efficiency for ANZ, ASB, BNZ and Westpac
for the entire period sits above 90%, with Kiwibank’s efficiency declining from around
93% in 2018 to around 87% in 2021.
148
117. Taken together, analysis of accounting and economic measures of efficiency suggest that New
Zealand’s banks (especially larger banks) are relatively efficient and likely not only using inputs in
an efficient manner, but also using an efficient combination of inputs.
Prices in a competitive market are set by a ‘marginal’ producer in most
markets and differing levels of profitability should be expected
118. In our submission on the PIP, we noted that in a market where firms are faced with differing
costs and capacity constraints, the supply curve can be ‘upward sloping’. In these cases, the
market price in equilibrium is set by the highest cost ‘marginal’ producer who will only make a
‘normal’ return at market prices. Lower cost producers or firms will make a margin above
(economic) costs in such a situation.
149
Above normal returns reflecting greater efficiency does
not necessarily indicate a competition problem.
150
119. This has previously been acknowledged by the Commission in their market study into the retail
grocery sector, stating that “if profitability is persistent in a competitive market, it will generally
be confined to a subset of firms that have some form of enduring competitive advantage such as
relatively lower costs”.
151
120. On both accounting and economic measures, larger banks such as ANZ, ASB, Westpac or BNZ
are found to be relatively efficient, compared to relatively smaller banks such as Kiwibank, TSB
Bank (TSB), Heartland, SBS or The Co-operative Bank (Co-op). We consider that the relatively
high profitability observed for ANZ, ASB, Westpac and BNZ
152
are driven by these observed
efficiencies. We reiterate again that care should be taken attributing excess profitability of a
subset of banks as an indication that the market for personal banking services is not workably
competitive.
121. In addition, the econometrics paper presents a fixed effects panel regression on the relationship
between market power and efficiency (that is, what is the relationship between efficiency
measures and market power as measured by the Lerner Index). They find both cost and profit
146
Ibid, at 10-11.
147
Ibid, at 8-9.
148
Ibid, at 11-12.
149
Gunnar Niels, Helen Jenkins and James Kavanagh Economics for Competition Lawyers (2nd Ed, Oxford University Press, Oxford, 2016) at
[1.32].
150
OXERA for the Office of Fair Trading “Assessing profitability in competition policy analysis – Economic discussion paper 6” (July 2003) at
[8.16], available at https://www.oxera.com/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/OFT-Assessing-profitability-1.pdf
151
Commerce Commission “Market study into the retail grocery sector – Final report” (8 March 2022) at [3.16].
152
See, for example, Commerce Commission “Personal banking services market study – Draft report” (21 March 2024) at [6.30]
Public Version | Profitability
44
efficiency to be statistically significant in explaining observed market power
153
(and we note that
the coefficients estimated suggest economic significance also).
122. While it is important to note that these results alone do not suggest causality, they do find that
“causality is more likely to run from efficiency to market power than the other way around”.
154
That is, they suggest that firms have market power (i.e., are able to price above cost) because
they are relatively efficient.
Is the persistency of the relatively higher profitability attributable to
regulatory conditions of entry and expansion?
123. The Commission states that they would “expect that the first-tier banks would have competed
away profits attributable to their relatively lower CTI ratio” under a workably competitive
market.
155
However, this implicitly suggests that the marginal producer is ANZ, ASB, Westpac or
BNZ, as opposed to Kiwibank, or a smaller firm such as TSB, Heartland, SBS or Co-op.
124. As discussed above, in most markets, any above normal profit levels will, under a competitive
market, be ‘competed’ away until the marginal firm is earning a normal return. Firms with a
lower cost structure (i.e., who are more efficient than the marginal firm) are still able to
generate an above normal return, even under a competitive market.
125. The Commission also states that under a workably competitive market they would expect to
“see less efficient firms seeking to capture, and compete away, some of those higher returns by
expanding”.
156
126. We agree. In a competitive market with no significant impediments to entry, exit or expansion,
we would expect over time, less efficient firms would seek to capture, and compete, away
higher returns by expanding. A consequence would also be much more variability in market
shares and positions over time.
127. However, the nature of personal banking services means that there are inherently conditions
which, to a certain extent, inhibit entry, exit or expansion. Fundamentally, New Zealand’s
financial regulatory framework is designed primarily to ensure financial stability which is
paramount given the systemic importance of the banking sector in any economy. As the
Commission notes, regulation is the single most important factor constraining new entry and the
ability of existing providers to expand and compete.
157
128. We invite the Commission to consider whether regulatory settings designed to ensure financial
stability explain, in large part, the persistence of the relatively higher profitability observed,
rather than a lack of workable competition between current participants (which, as discussed
above, we do not consider is supported by a consideration of the evidence in the round).
129. Specifically, we invite the Commission to consider that:
129.1. Banks such as Kiwibank, TSB, Heartland, SBS or Co-op are the marginal producers for
personal banking services, meaning ANZ, ASB, Westpac or BNZ would generate above
normal returns, even under a competitive market.
129.2. The reason that higher returns of ANZ, ASB, Westpac or BNZ have not be competed away
are largely due to the regulatory framework that is designed primarily to ensure financial
stability.
153
Professor Dimitris Margaritis & Dr Maryam Hasannasab “Market power in banking: A study of New Zealand banks” (March 2024) at Table
1.
154
Ibid, at 19.
155
Commerce Commission “Personal banking services market study – Draft report” (21 March 2024) at [C95].
156
Ibid, at [C97].
157
Ibid, at 159.
Public Version | Appendix VAR estimation procedure
45
Appendix VAR estimation
procedure
130. This appendix sets out the technical details of how we estimated VAR models of advertised
mortgage and term deposit rates and carried out hypothesis testing for causality.
Factors relevant to our chosen estimation procedure
131. To adequately assess the responsiveness of banks’ advertised mortgage and term deposit rates
to each other, we consider that an estimation technique needs to take into account the
following factors:
131.1. The potential that one bank’s advertised rates may impact another bank’s advertised
rates, which may, in turn, impact another bank’s advertised rates and so on. In other
words, the estimation technique needs to account for the fact that there may be
dynamic interrelationships and feedback loops between banks’ advertised rates and that
they may therefore be determined ‘endogenously’.
131.2. The potential that a bank’s advertised rates may be impacted by changes in wholesale
costs, and in this case, changes in a relevant cost benchmark.
132. Given these factors, we decided that a VAR model would be a suitable choice. A VAR model
allows us to model how a set of endogenous (determined within model) variables interact with,
and explain, each other as well as any exogenous (determined outside of model) variables.
133. Specifically, we estimated a VAR model where each bank’s rates are a function of the lagged
values of its own past rates, lagged values of past competitor rates, and relevant wholesale cost
benchmarks as additional explanatory variables exogenous to the system.
Advantages and disadvantages of the chosen VAR model
Our VAR model does not require any priors
134. VAR models are a flexible estimate technique. A VAR model typically expresses each variable of
interest as a linear function of its own past values, the past values of other variables being
considered and a serially uncorrelated error term.
158
135. VAR models do not require a priori theoretical knowledge about the underlying relationships
among modelled variables. While the lack of theoretical underpinnings of underlying
relationships among modelled variables is typically a criticism of VAR models, we consider it is
an advantage in this instance.
136. As we discussed above, the economic literature that is relevant to differentiated dynamic
competition among several firms suggest a multiplicity of potential outcomes, depending on a
number of features that may be present in the market.
137. By using a VAR model, we are able to remain agnostic about the nature of interdependencies
between banks’ advertised rates and to test which bank’s advertised rates statistically
significantly explain the advertised rates of other banks.
138. Our VAR models are specified solely based on the data observed. Because we let the data
determine the properties and specifications of our model, rather than theoretical principles or
priors about the nature of the market for personal banking services, we can test for what the
158
James H Stock and Mark W Watson “Vector Autoregressions” (2001) 15(4) Journal of Economic Perspectives 101 at 102.
Public Version | Appendix VAR estimation procedure
46
specification of our models says about the competitive nature of advertised rates for mortgages
and term deposits between banks.
Our VAR model does not allow for contemporaneous impacts
139. As noted previously, we acknowledge that a bank’s advertised rates in one week may be
impacted by another bank’s advertised rates in that same week (i.e., contemporaneously impact
a bank’s advertised rates), in addition to previous weeks’ advertised rates. While there are
techniques to model such contemporaneous interactions between banks, they involve setting
assumptions about the nature and timing of competition between banks, and in particular, the
order in which changes in one bank’s rates impact other banks’ rates.
159
140. We consider that making such assumptions would go towards making assumptions around the
nature of competition between banks (i.e., presupposing the order of how each bank’s
advertised rates respond to those of other banks).
141. For this reason, we continued to estimate the VAR regression with the assumption that past
values of a banks advertised rates impact rates in a particular week. In addition, given that we
applied relatively high frequency weekly data, we would expect in many instances, the past
week’s advertised rates would indeed impact a bank’s advertised rates in the current week.
142. We also note that in the Draft Report the Commission finds that pricing decisions are typically
made by a pricing committee which usually meets weekly (or in response to major events).
160
As
such, we believe it is reasonable to use a model whereby pricing decisions are made weekly,
based on observed historical rates in the market (up to the week prior) and wholesale costs
today, as this is likely to be representative of the information the pricing committees have to
hand.
Mortgage rate dataset
143. We used advertised personal home loan mortgage rates obtained from interest.co.nz to
undertake our analysis. Interest.co.nz maintains a database of advertised rates by product and
institution (including registered banks, brands of registered banks and non-bank financial
institutions) as at Friday of each week, from January 2002 to November 2023. This dataset is
also shared with the Reserve Bank of New Zealand (RBNZ) and is therefore considered as a
credible dataset.
144. For 2-year to 5-year fixed products, our analysis covers August 2010 onwards only due to swap
rate data availability from the RBNZ.
145. This dataset contains, for each institution, their ‘best rate’. This may take the form, for example,
of a discounted rate for borrowers with a loan-to-value (LVR) ratio below 80%. In 2022, 92% of
new residential mortgage commitments by value had an LVR of 80% or below.
161
This means
that the ‘best rate’ is likely to capture more of the market than a ‘standard rate’. Importantly, it
also means the dataset is like-for-like and internally consistent.
146. We undertook cleaning and reformatting of this dataset to obtain a time series of rates by
institution and product duration which was used to fit our regression models. Although we had
data for non-bank institutions, we decided to consider only registered banks. The rates of
registered banks other than ANZ, ASB, Westpac, BNZ and Kiwibank were averaged into an ‘Other
159
In particular, we could have estimated a SVAR that allows for contemporaneous interactions between advertised rates of banks. However,
this would require an explicit assumption be made with regards to Cholesky ordering. Essentially, this means imposing the order with which
variables in the SVAR are solved as an underlying assumption. In the context of mortgage rates, this would require assuming a ‘first-mover’,
‘second-mover’ and so on, which would risk presupposing a given outcome. Therefore, we concluded that a contemporaneous model would
not be suitable.
160
Commerce Commission “Personal banking services market study Draft Report” (21 March 2024) at [4.28] to [4.30].
161
Deloitte Access Economics analysis of RBNZ “New residential mortgage lending by LVR – C30 (Aug 2013 current)”, available at
https://www.rbnz.govt.nz/statistics/series/lending-and-monetary/new-residential-mortgage-lending-by-loan-to-valuation-ratio
Public Version | Appendix VAR estimation procedure
47
Banks’ variable.
162
We did not specify which banks were averaged into this variable. Instead, any
observations for a given date which were from a registered bank (determined by the RBNZ list of
registered
163
and formerly registered
164
banks) which was not ANZ, ASB, Westpac, BNZ or
Kiwibank, were averaged together to produce the ‘other bank’ variable.
Term deposit rate dataset
147. Like with the mortgage rate data, we used advertised term deposit rates obtained from
interest.co.nz to undertake our term deposit analysis. interest.co.nz maintains a database of
advertised rates by product and institution (including registered banks, brands of registered
banks and non-bank financial institutions) as at Friday of each week, from January 2002 to
November 2023. This dataset is also shared with the RBNZ, and is therefore considered as a
credible dataset.
148. The term deposit dataset from interest.co.nz contains different rates for products with a
different minimum deposit amount (e.g., $10,000). This meant that for a given date, some
institutions had multiple term deposit rates for different minimum deposit products (which may
or may not be the same rate).
149. We opted to analyse the rates for the $10,000 and $50,000 minimum term deposits across the
available terms of 6-months to 5-years. There were two primary reasons for this:
149.1. The availability of interest rate data for the $10,000 and $50,000 minimum deposit rates
were largely consistent across all of the major banks and most of the other registered
banks for the entire time span of the dataset (January 2002 to November 2023). Some
minimum deposit rates were discontinued after a certain point in time, and others were
only offered by a small subset of banks in the dataset.
149.2. Data released by the RBNZ in December 2023 relating to banks’ balance sheets reveals
that term deposits with minimum amounts of $10,000 and $50,000 capture
approximately 82% and 38% of the market respectively, by count of term deposit
accounts as of December 2023.
165
This suggests the products we chose to analyse are
representative of the deposit market and capture the majority of term deposit accounts
in New Zealand.
150. We undertook cleaning and reformatting of this dataset to obtain a time series of rates by
institution and product duration separately for the $10,000 and $50,000 minimum deposit rate
products, which was used to fit our regression models. Although we had data for non-bank
institutions, we decided to consider only registered banks. The rates of registered banks other
than ANZ, ASB, Westpac, BNZ and Kiwibank were averaged into an ‘other bank’ variable.
166
151. The banks contained in the ‘other bank’ variable differs between the $10,000 and $50,000
minimum deposit data, because not all of the other registered banks were consistent across
these two offerings. As with the mortgage rate data, the banks included in the ‘other banks’
162
For example, other banks included in the VAR model for advertised floating mortgage rates were Bank of China, HSBC, HSBC Premier,
Heartland, ICBC, Kookmin, National Bank, SBS, TSB and Westpac Trust. For the VAR model for advertised $10k minimum 6-month term
deposit rates, the other banks variable consisted of Bank Direct, Bank of Baroda, Bank of India, Co-operative Bank, HSBC, ICBC, Kookmin,
National Bank and TSB. As the interest.co.nz dataset we used extends back to 2002, several older sub-brands, such as Westpac Trust, are
present in our dataset. To account for the possibility that such sub-brands followed and executed different competitive strategies, we
included these within other banks variable.
163
RBNZ “Registered banks in New Zealand”, available at https://www.rbnz.govt.nz/regulation-and-supervision/cross-sector-
oversight/registers-of-entities-we-regulate/registered-banks-in-new-zealand
164
RBNZ “Banks no longer registered in New Zealand”, available at https://www.rbnz.govt.nz/regulation-and-supervision/cross-sector-
oversight/registers-of-entities-we-regulate/banks-no-longer-registered-in-new-zealand
165
RBNZ “Banks: Liabilities – Deposits by size (number) (S46)”, available at https://www.rbnz.govt.nz/statistics/series/registered-banks/banks-
liabilities-deposits-by-size-number
166
For example, other banks included in the VAR model for advertised floating mortgage rates were Bank of China, HSBC, HSBC Premium,
Heartland, ICBC, Kookmin, National Bank, SBS, TSB and Westpac Trust. For the VAR model for advertised $10k minimum 6-month term
deposit rates, the other banks variable consisted of Bank Direct, Bank of Baroda, Bank of India, Co-operative Bank, HSBC, ICBC, Kookmin,
National Bank and TSB
Public Version | Appendix VAR estimation procedure
48
variable was determined by the registered banks contained in the dataset who were not ANZ,
ASB, BNZ, Westpac or Kiwibank.
Model specification and robustness testing
152. Table 6 shows the VAR equation specifications we applied to both the mortgage and term
deposit rates.
Table 6: VAR equations
Regression equations estimated

 


   


 


   


 


 
 


 


   


 


 







 



 




 


   


 


   


 


 
 


 


   


 


 







   



 




 


 


 


 


 


 
 


 


   


 


 







 



 




 


 


 


 


 


 
 


 


   


 


 



 



   



 




 


   


 


   


 


 
 


 


   


 


 



 



   



 




 


   


 


 


 


 
 


 


   


 


 



 



   



 



Where “Other banks Rate” is a simple average of all other registered banks’ advertised rates
Where “i” is the selected lag length
Source: Deloitte Access Economics
153. Using the system of equations outlined in Table 6, we fitted a VAR model for floating, 1-year, 2-
year, 3-year, 4-year and 5-year mortgage rates, and the 6-month, 1-year, 2-year, 3-year, 4-year,
and 5-year term deposit rates for both the $10,000 and $50,000 minimum deposit products.
The lag length was initially determined using STATA’s varsoc command,
167
and was increased as
required to resolve any autocorrelation. We refer to this model as the ‘underlying VAR’.
154. We have used levels for all the variables in our model. This means that our data may be non-
stationary and/or cointegrated. Testing for stationarity confirms that our variables are non-
stationary of order one. This means that our VAR model cannot be used for certain purposes,
such as impulse response function (IRF) analysis or forecasting. However, as discussed below,
167
STATA “Varsoc – Obtain lag-order selection statistics for VARs and VECMs”, available at https://www.stata.com/manuals/tsvarsoc.pdf
Public Version | Appendix VAR estimation procedure
49
there are ways to undertake statistical inference on VAR models with non-stationary and/or
cointegrated processes.
155. We then undertook a series of robustness and goodness of fit tests on the underlying VAR
models, including stationarity and white noise testing of residuals and ensuring the VAR model
was stable. The results of this testing indicated that the models were robust, stable and not
impacted by autocorrelation or missing explanatory variables.
Table 7: Underlying VAR specification for advertised mortgage rates
Floating
1-year
2-year
3-year
4-year
5-year
Lags
8 lags
9 lags
3 lags
4 lags
4 lags
4 lags
Exogenous
variable
90-day bank bill
yield
90-day bank bill
yield
2-year swap rate
3-year swap rate
4-year swap rate
5-year swap rate
Stability
Satisfied varstable
168
stability test
Satisfied varstable
stability test
Satisfied varstable
stability test
Satisfied varstable
stability test
Satisfied varstable
stability test
Satisfied varstable
stability test
Outcome of
residual
testing
169
Residuals of each
equation stationary
and pass white
noise test
Residuals of each
equation stationary
and pass white
noise test
Residuals of each
equation stationary
and pass white
noise test (noting
other bank residual
only passes at 1%
level)
Residuals of each
equation stationary
and pass white
noise test (noting
other bank residual
only passes at 1%
and 5% level)
Residuals of each
equation stationary
and pass white
noise test (except
ASB which fails at
conventional levels
we note the
residuals are still
stationary and
visually appear
robust)
Residuals of each
equation stationary
and pass white
noise test (except
ASB which fails at
conventional levels
we note the
residuals are still
stationary and
visually appear
robust)
Source: Deloitte Access Economics analysis of interest.co.nz data
156. We concluded from these tests that our model is likely to be robust. The white noise test on the
residuals indicated that autocorrelation is likely not impacting the model. We note that the ASB
residuals for the 4-year and 5-year models did not pass a Portmanteau white noise test.
However, every other residual did, and these passed stationarity tests and upon visual
inspection appeared suitable.
168
STATA “Varstable – Check the stability condition of VAR or SVAR estimates”, available at https://www.stata.com/manuals/tsvarstable.pdf
169
Stationarity of residuals was tested using STATA’s dfuller command, while white noise was tested using the wntestq command
(Portmanteau test) and results are tested against all significance levels unless noted otherwise.
Public Version | Appendix VAR estimation procedure
50
Table 8: Underlying VAR specification for advertised $10,000 minimum term deposit rates
6-month
1-year
2-year
3-year
4-year
5-year
Lags
13 lags
12 lags
7 lags
5 lags
3 lags
3 lags
Exogenous
variable
90-day bank bill
yield
90-day bank bill
yield
2-year swap rate
3-year swap rate
4-year swap rate
5-year swap rate
Stability
Satisfied varstable
stability test
Satisfied varstable
stability test
Satisfied varstable
stability test
Satisfied varstable
stability test
Satisfied varstable
stability test
Satisfied varstable
stability test
Outcome of
residual testing
Residuals of each
equation stationary
and pass white
noise test
Residuals of each
equation stationary
and pass white
noise test
Residuals of each
equation stationary
and pass white
noise test
Residuals of each
equation stationary
and pass white
noise test
Residuals of each
equation stationary
and pass white
noise test
Residuals of each
equation stationary
and pass white
noise test
Source: Deloitte Access Economics analysis of interest.co.nz data
Table 9: Underlying VAR specification for advertised $50,000 minimum term deposit rates
6-month
1-year
2-year
3-year
4-year
5-year
Lags
9 lags
8 lags
6 lags
3 lags
3 lags
3 lags
Exogenous
variable
90-day bank bill
yield
90-day bank bill
yield
2-year swap rate
3-year swap rate
4-year swap rate
5-year swap rate
Stability
Satisfied varstable
stability test
Satisfied varstable
stability test
Satisfied varstable
stability test
Satisfied varstable
stability test
Satisfied varstable
stability test
Satisfied varstable
stability test
Outcome of
residual testing
Residuals of each
equation stationary
and pass white
noise test
Residuals of each
equation stationary
and pass white
noise test
Residuals of each
equation stationary
and pass white
noise test
Residuals of each
equation stationary
and pass white
noise test
Residuals of each
equation stationary
and pass white
noise test
Residuals of each
equation stationary
and pass white
noise test
Source: Deloitte Access Economics analysis of interest.co.nz data
157. We concluded from these tests that our model is robust. The white noise test on the residuals
indicates that autocorrelation is likely not impacting the results.
Public Version | Appendix VAR estimation procedure
51
Causality testing
158. Because a VAR model represents a system of interacting equations, it is not possible to simply
examine the variable coefficients and their respective statistical significance to determine
whether an endogenous variable is statistically significant in explaining another.
170
Instead, a
test which accounts for how variable values flow through the entire VAR system is required to
further test whether there are causal relationships in our model.
159. A commonly used statistical hypothesis test for causality in a VAR model is Granger-causality.
Intuitively, Granger-causality asks whether the inclusion of a variable and its lags in a model
produces better estimates of the dependent variable (that is, are the coefficients on the lags
statistically different from zero) then if we had not included this variable.
171
160. Intuitively, Bank X’s rates can be said to Granger-cause those of Bank Y if Bank Y’s rates can be
better predicted by a model incorporating the histories of both X and Y than Y alone. The null
hypothesis of a Granger-causality test is that X does not Granger-cause Y. Therefore, rejection of
the null indicates that X does Granger-cause Y.
161. For this analysis, we concluded that if the null hypothesis can be rejected at conventional
significance levels, then our model is indicating that there is likely a causal relationship. If Bank X
is concluded to Granger-cause the rates of Bank Y, then our model is indicating that historically
Bank X has had an impact on Bank Y’s rates – at least with regards to advertised rates.
162. However, as noted above, we found the processes in our VAR model to be non-stationary and
suspected they may be possibly co-integrated. While usually you could take first-difference or
logarithm to overcome the non-stationarity issue, this can result in lost information. Therefore,
we opted to leave our model in levels and adopt an established approach to undertaking
statistical inference on VAR models with possible non-stationary and/or cointegrated processes.
163. Toda and Yamamoto set out an approach to undertaking statistical inference on VAR models
with potentially non-stationary and/or cointegrated processes in their 1995 paper.
172
They
discuss that undertaking pre-tests for stationarity and cointegration can create “severe pretest
biases” when undertaking statistical inference. Therefore, when the nature of cointegrating
relationships or of the unit roots is of interest, these pre-tests are a useful exercise. But as in our
case, when they are not of interest, it is more desirable to have a testing approach which is
“robust to the integration and cointegration properties of the process so as to avoid possible
pretest biases”.
164. When data is non-stationary, the Wald test statistic for Granger noncausality has a nonstandard
asymptotic distribution and when cointegrating relationships are present, we require pretesting
of the cointegrating ranks which can cause size distortions in the Wald test for Granger
noncausality. This means that it would not be appropriate to simply undertake testing for
Granger causality on these VAR models.
165. Toda and Yamamoto show that even if our processes in levels are non-stationary and potentially
cointegrated, we can apply the usual lag selection method as standard asymptotic theory holds
for this. Further, they show that if after selecting a VAR system with lag order of k, and which is
suspected to have an order of integration at most of d, then we can estimate a (d+k) order VAR
model and ignore the coefficients on the last d lags (as we assume these to be zero), then we
can test linear and nonlinear restrictions on the first k coefficients using standard asymptotic
theory.
170
This is because variables in a VAR model may have a first order, second order, and so on, effect on the system. For example, a change in
the rates of Bank A may impact those of Bank B and Bank C initially. The consequential change in rates of Bank B and C will impact those of
each other as well as Bank A and so on. Because of this effect, it is not sufficient to simply examine the coefficient and statistical significance
of a variable in the VAR model.
171
J.M. Wooldridge “Introductory Econometrics: A modern approach – 6e” (2016) at 590.
172
Hiro Y Toda and Taku Yamamoto “Statistical inference in vector autoregressions with possibly integrated processes” (1995) 66(1-2) Journal
of Econometrics 225-250.
Public Version | Appendix VAR estimation procedure
52
166. By including additional lags, Toda and Yamamoto showed that standard asymptotic theory holds
when testing for restrictions on coefficients, even if our processes are non-stationary and/or
cointegrated. This can be done without any pre-tests to confirm these properties. Because
standard asymptotic theory on testing restrictions holds, this model with additional lags is
suitable for use in testing for Granger causality.
167. Therefore, we refitted our underlying VAR models with an additional lag (included as an
exogenous variable). This is because we suspect our processes to be integrated of order one at
most. This model with the additional lag was used for Granger causality testing.
Limitations of analysis
168. Interpretation of the results and making inferences from them about the nature of competition
requires careful consideration of what our VAR analysis does and does not model.
169. The VAR model captures historical trends in how the mortgage and term deposit rates
advertised by each bank are related to the rates advertised in the past by both the bank being
modelled and other banks, as well as an exogenous wholesale rate benchmark. Therefore, it
provides a one-dimensional view of competition and price setting.
170. Because of the issues discussed above, our model is only suitable for causality testing. Causality
testing can tell us if a causal relationship is observed, but it can’t tell us about the extent of the
relationship. Therefore, we were not able to test the relative magnitude of relationships.
171. Our analysis was undertaken on advertised rates. We understand that advertised rates can
differ from the rates actually available to consumers. Therefore, our analysis is likely to
understate price responsiveness and the prevalence of causal relationships.
172. As we note earlier in this report, banks also compete on many other dimensions (e.g.,
discounted rates, quality of service, reputation etc.) which are not captured by this model.
Banks may respond to competitive factors across different dimensions.
Public Version | Appendix VAR estimation procedure
53
Deloitte refers to one or more of Deloitte Touche Tohmatsu Limited (“DTTL”), its global
network of member firms, and their related entities (collectively, the “Deloitte
organisation”). DTTL (also referred to as “Deloitte Global”) and each of its member firms and
related entities are legally separate and independent entities, which cannot obligate or bind
each other in respect of third parties. DTTL and each DTTL member firm and related entity is
liable only for its own acts and omissions, and not those of each other. DTTL does not
provide services to clients. Please see www.deloitte.com/about to learn more.
Deloitte Asia Pacific Limited is a company limited by guarantee and a member firm of DTTL.
Members of Deloitte Asia Pacific Limited and their related entities, each of which are
separate and independent legal entities, provide services from more than 100 cities across
the region, including Auckland, Bangkok, Beijing, Hanoi, Hong Kong, Jakarta, Kuala Lumpur,
Manila, Melbourne, Osaka, Seoul, Shanghai, Singapore, Sydney, Taipei and Tokyo.
Deloitte is a leading global provider of audit and assurance, consulting, financial advisory,
risk advisory, tax and related services. Our global network of member firms and related
entities in more than 150 countries and territories (collectively, the “Deloitte organisation”)
serves four out of five Fortune Global 500® companies. Learn how Deloitte’s approximately
312,000 people make an impact that matters at www.deloitte.com.
Deloitte New Zealand brings together more than 1400 specialist professionals providing
audit, tax, technology and systems, strategy and performance improvement, risk
management, corporate finance, business recovery, forensic and accounting services. Our
people are based in Auckland, Hamilton, Rotorua, Wellington, Christchurch, Queenstown
and Dunedin, serving clients that range from New Zealand’s largest companies and public
sector organisations to smaller businesses with ambition to grow. For more information
about Deloitte in New Zealand, look to our website www.deloitte.co.nz.
© 2024. For information, contact Deloitte Global.